Malthusian catastrophe: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
merge from Malthusianism intro
reverse merge and redirect to Malthusianism after discussion at Talk:Malthusian catastrophe#Merge Proposal with Malthusian Trap
Tag: New redirect
 
(17 intermediate revisions by 2 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
#REDIRECT [[Malthusianism]] {{R from merge}}
{{short description|Prediction of a forced return to subsistence-level conditions once population growth has outpaced agricultural production}}
{{mergefrom|Malthusianism|date=September 2020}}
[[File:Thomas Robert Malthus.jpg|thumb|Thomas Robert Malthus, after whom the Malthusian trap is named]]

'''Malthusianism''' is the idea that [[Malthusian growth model|population growth is potentially exponential]] while the growth of the food supply or other [[resources]] is [[linear growth|linear]], which eventually reduces living standards to the point of triggering a population die off. This event, called a '''Malthusian catastrophe''' (also known as '''Malthusian trap''', '''population trap''', '''Malthusian check''', '''Malthusian crisis''', '''Malthusian spectre''', '''Malthusian crunch'''), occurs when [[population growth]] outpaces [[agriculture|agricultural]] [[Production (economics)|production]], causing population to be limited by [[famine]] or [[war]]. These concepts derive from the political and economic thought of the Reverend [[Thomas Robert Malthus]], as laid out in his 1798 writings, ''[[An Essay on the Principle of Population]]''. Malthus suggested that while technological advances could increase a society's supply of resources, such as food, and thereby improve the [[standard of living]], the resource abundance would enable [[population growth]], which would eventually bring the per capita supply of resources back to its original level. Some economists contend that since the [[industrial revolution]], mankind has broken out of the trap.<ref name="Galor (2005)">{{cite book |last=Galor |first=Oded |year=2005 |chapter=From Stagnation to Growth: Unified Growth Theory |title=Handbook of Economic Growth |volume=1 |pages=171–293 |publisher=Elsevier |chapter-url=https://ideas.repec.org/h/eee/grochp/1-04.html }}</ref><ref name="Clark2007">{{cite book |last=Clark |first=Gregory |year=2007 |title=A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World |publisher=Princeton University Press |isbn=978-0-691-12135-2 |title-link=A Farewell to Alms }}</ref> Others argue that the continuation of [[extreme poverty]] indicates that the Malthusian trap continues to operate.<ref>Julia Zinkina & [[Andrey Korotayev]]. [https://www.academia.edu/6823642/EXPLOSIVE_POPULATION_GROWTH_IN_TROPICAL_AFRICA_CRUCIAL_OMISSION_IN_DEVELOPMENT_FORECASTS_EMERGING_RISKS_AND_WAY_OUT Explosive Population Growth in Tropical Africa: Crucial Omission in Development Forecasts (Emerging Risks and Way Out). ''World Futures'' 70/2 (2014): 120–39].</ref> Others further argue that due to lack of food availability coupled with excessive pollution, [[developing countries]] show more evidence of the trap.<ref>{{Cite web|url=http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/197551/2/WP59.pdf|title=The Malthusian Trap and Development in Pre-Industrial Societies: A View Differing from the Standard One|last=Tisdell|first=Clem|date=1 January 2015|website=University of Queensland|access-date=26 February 2017}}</ref>

== Malthus' theoretical argument ==

In 1798, [[Thomas Robert Malthus|Thomas Malthus]] proposed his theory in ''[[An Essay on the Principle of Population]]''.

He argued that society has a natural propensity to increase its population, a propensity that causes population growth to be the best measure of the happiness of a people: "The happiness of a country does not depend, absolutely, upon its poverty, or its riches, upon its youth, or its age, upon its being thinly, or fully inhabited, but upon the rapidity with which it is increasing, upon the degree in which the yearly increase of food approaches to the yearly increase of an unrestricted population."<ref>Malthus, ''Essay on the Principle of Population'', Ch. VII.</ref>

However, the propensity for population increase also leads to a natural cycle of abundance and shortages:
{{quote|We will suppose the means of subsistence in any country just equal to the easy support of its inhabitants. The constant effort towards population...increases the number of people before the means of subsistence are increased. The food therefore which before supported seven millions, must now be divided among seven millions and a half or eight millions. The poor consequently must live much worse, and many of them be reduced to severe distress. The number of labourers also being above the proportion of the work in the market, the price of labour must tend toward a decrease; while the price of provisions would at the same time tend to rise. The labourer therefore must work harder to earn the same as he did before. During this season of distress, the discouragements to marriage, and the difficulty of rearing a family are so great, that population is at a stand. In the mean time the cheapness of labour, the plenty of labourers, and the necessity of an increased industry amongst them, encourage cultivators to employ more labour upon their land; to turn up fresh soil, and to manure and improve more completely what is already in tillage; till ultimately the means of subsistence become in the same proportion to the population as at the period from which we set out. The situation of the labourer being then again tolerably comfortable, the restraints to population are in some degree loosened; and the same retrograde and progressive movements with respect to happiness are repeated.|Thomas Malthus, 1798. ''[[An Essay on the Principle of Population]]'', Chapter II.}}

{{quote|Famine seems to be the last, the most dreadful resource of nature. The power of population is so superior to the power of the earth to produce subsistence for man, that premature death must in some shape or other visit the human race. The vices of mankind are active and able ministers of depopulation. They are the precursors in the great army of destruction, and often finish the dreadful work themselves. But should they fail in this war of extermination, sickly seasons, epidemics, pestilence, and plague advance in terrific array, and sweep off their thousands and tens of thousands. Should success be still incomplete, gigantic inevitable famine stalks in the rear, and with one mighty blow levels the population with the food of the world.|Thomas Malthus, 1798. ''[[An Essay on the Principle of Population]]''. Chapter VII, p. 61<ref name="Oxford World's Classics reprint">Oxford World's Classics reprint</ref>}}

Malthus faced opposition from economists both during his life and since. A vocal critic several decades later was [[Friedrich Engels]].<ref>{{cite book |title= The Condition of the Working-Class in England in 1844 |last=Engels |first=Fredrick |year=1892 |publisher= Swan Sonnenschein & Co |location= London |url= http://www.fordham.edu/halsall/mod/1844engels.html }} Engels wrote that poverty and poor living conditions in 1844 had largely disappeared.</ref><ref>{{cite book |title= The Escape from Hunger and Premature Death, 1700–2100|last=Fogel |first=Robert W.|author-link= Robert_Fogel|year=2004 |publisher= Cambridge University Press|location= London |isbn= 978-0521808781 }}</ref>

== Modern formulation ==
The modern formulation of the Malthusian theory was developed by Qumarul Ashraf and [[Oded Galor]].<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Ashraf|first1=Quamrul|last2=Galor|first2=Oded|date=2011|title=Dynamics and Stagnation in the Malthusian Epoch|journal=American Economic Review|volume=101|issue=5|pages=2003–2041|doi=10.1257/aer.101.5.2003|pmid=25506082|pmc=4262154}}</ref> Their theoretical structure suggests that as long as: (i) higher income has a positive effect on reproductive success, and (ii) land is limited factor of production, then technological progress has only a temporary effect in income per capita. While in the short-run technological progress increases income per capita, resource abundance created by technological progress would enable [[population growth]], and would eventually bring the per capita income back to its original long-run level.

The testable prediction of the theory is that during the Malthusian epoch technologically advanced economies were characterized by higher population density, but their level of income per capita was not different than the level in societies that are technologically backward.

== Preventive vs. positive population controls==

Malthus proposed two types of "checks" that limit population growth based on food supply at any given time:

* A ''preventive check'' is a conscious decision to delay marriage or abstain from procreation based on a lack of resources.<ref name=":0">{{Cite web|url=http://www.esp.org/books/malthus/population/malthus.pdf|title=An Essay on The Principle of Population|last=Malthus|first=Thomas Robert|date=1798|website=Electronic Scholarly Publishing Project|access-date=29 March 2018}}</ref> These include moral restraints or legislative action — for example the choice by a private citizen to engage in [[abstinence]] and delay marriage until their finances become balanced, or restriction of [[marriage|legal marriage]] or parenting rights for persons deemed "deficient" or "unfit" by the government. Malthus argued that people are incapable of ignoring the consequences of uncontrolled population growth, and would intentionally avoid contributing to it.<ref name=":0" />

* A ''positive check'' is any event or circumstance that shortens the human life span. The primary examples of this are [[war]], [[epidemic|plague]] and [[famine]].<ref name=":0" /> However, poor health and economic conditions are also considered instances of positive checks.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Simkins|first=Charles|date=2001|title=Can South Africa Avoid a Malthusian Positive Check?|jstor=20027682|journal=Daedalus|volume=130|issue=1|pages=123–150|pmid=19068951}}</ref> When these lead to high rates of premature death, the result is termed a [[Malthusian catastrophe]]. The adjacent diagram depicts the abstract point at which such an event would occur, in terms of existing population and food supply: when the population reaches or exceeds the capacity of the shared supply, positive checks are forced to occur, restoring balance. (In reality the situation would be significantly more nuanced due to complex regional and individual disparities around access to food, water, and other resources.)










==Neo-Malthusian theory==

{{See also|Malthusianism}}
The rapid increase in the global population since 1900 exemplifies Malthus's predicted population patterns, whereby expansion of food supply has encouraged population growth. "Neo-Malthusianism" may be used as a label for those who are concerned that [[human overpopulation]] may increase [[resource depletion]] or [[environmental degradation]] to a degree that is not [[sustainability|sustainable]]. Many in [[environmentalism|environmental movements]] express concern over the potential dangers of population growth.<ref name="intellectual roots">{{cite journal|title=The Post War Intellectual Roots of the Population Bomb |author1=Pierre Desrochers |author2=Christine Hoffbauer |journal=[[International Policy Network|The Electronic Journal of Sustainable Development]] |url=http://www.dpi.inpe.br/sil/cst310/Aula2_fundamentos/THE_POST_WAR_INTELLECTUAL_ROOTS_OF_THE_POPULATION_BOMB_-_FAIRFIELD_OSBORNS_OUR_PLUNDERED_PLANET_AND_WILLIAM_VOGTS_ROAD_TO_SURVIVAL_IN_RETROSPECT.pdf |year=2009 |volume=1 |issue=3 |access-date=2010-02-01 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120302185414/http://www.dpi.inpe.br/sil/cst310/Aula2_fundamentos/THE_POST_WAR_INTELLECTUAL_ROOTS_OF_THE_POPULATION_BOMB_-_FAIRFIELD_OSBORNS_OUR_PLUNDERED_PLANET_AND_WILLIAM_VOGTS_ROAD_TO_SURVIVAL_IN_RETROSPECT.pdf |archive-date=March 2, 2012 }}{{Unreliable source?|date=April 2013}}<!-- maybe highlight in text that opinions are from fake journal from pressure group, no CiteSeerX cite --></ref> In 1968, ecologist [[Garrett Hardin]] published an influential essay in ''Science'' that drew heavily from Malthusian theory. His essay, [[Tragedy of the commons|"The Tragedy of the Commons,"]] argued that "a finite world can support only a finite population" and that "freedom to breed will bring ruin to all."<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Hardin|first=Garrett|year=1968|title=The Tragedy of the Commons|journal=Science|volume=162|issue=3859|pages=1243–1248|doi=10.1126/science.162.3859.1243|pmid=17756331|bibcode=1968Sci...162.1243H|doi-access=free}}</ref> The [[Club of Rome]] published a famous book entitled ''[[The Limits to Growth]]'' in 1972.<ref>{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=UOcUZ9uquhEC&pg=PA2 |title=Taking Nature Into Account: A Report to the Club of Rome |editor=Wouter van Dieren |year=1995 |publisher=Springer Books |isbn=978-0-387-94533-0}}</ref> [[Paul R. Ehrlich]] is a prominent neo-Malthusian who first raised concerns in 1968 with the publication of ''[[The Population Bomb]]''.

[[File:Wheat yields in Least Developed Countries.svg|thumb|right|200px|Wheat yields in developing countries since 1961, in kg/[[hectare|ha]]. The steep rise in crop yields in the U.S. began in the 1940s. The percentage of growth was fastest in the early rapid growth stage. In developing countries maize yields are still rapidly rising.<ref>{{Cite journal
| last1 = Fischer
| first1 =R. A.
| last2 =Byerlee
| first2 =Eric
| last3 =Edmeades
| first3 =E. O.
| title = Can Technology Deliver on the Yield Challenge to 2050
|journal=Expert Meeting on How to Feed the World
|pages=12
|publisher= Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations
| url = ftp://ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/012/ak977e/ak977e00.pdf
}}</ref>]]

A study conducted in 2009<ref>[http://www.fao.org/wsfs/forum2050/wsfs-background-documents/issues-briefs/en/ How to feed the world in 2050]</ref> said that food production will have to increase by 70% over the next 40 years, and food production in the developing world will need to double.<ref>[http://www.fao.org/news/story/en/item/35571/icode/ 2050: A third more mouths to feed]</ref>
This is a result of the increasing population (world population will increase to 9.1 billion in 2050, where there are already 7.8 billion people today). The [[effects of global warming]] (floods, droughts, extreme weather events, ...) are expected to negatively affect food production, with different impacts in different regions.<ref>[https://www.ipcc.ch/report/srccl/ Climate Change and Land report]</ref><ref>[https://www.nytimes.com/2019/08/08/climate/climate-change-food-supply.html Climate Change Threatens the World’s Food Supply, United Nations Warns]</ref> As a result, we will need to use the scarce natural resources more efficiently and adapt to climate change.<ref>[http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/europe/8303434.stm Food production 'must rise 70%']</ref> The use of agricultural resources for [[biofuels]] may also put downward pressure on food availability.<ref>[https://www.populationinstitute.org/resources/populationonline/issue/1/8/ FAO says Food Production must Rise by 70%]</ref>

==Evidence in support==
Research indicates that technological superiority and higher land productivity had significant positive effects on population density but insignificant effects on the standard of living during the time period 1–1500 AD.<ref name="Ashraf and Galor, 2010">{{cite journal |last1=Ashraf |first1=Quamrul |first2=Oded |last2=Galor |year=2011 |title=Dynamics and Stagnation in the Malthusian Epoch |journal=[[American Economic Review]] |volume=101 |issue=5 |pages=2003–41 |doi=10.1257/aer.101.5.2003 |pmid=25506082 |pmc=4262154 }}</ref> In addition, scholars have reported on the lack of a significant trend of wages in various places over the world for very long stretches of time.<ref name="Clark2007" /><ref>{{cite journal |last=Allen |first=R. C. |title=The Great Divergence in European Wages and Prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War |journal=Explorations in Economic History |volume=38 |issue=4 |pages=411–47 |year=2001 |doi=10.1006/exeh.2001.0775 }}</ref> In Babylonia during the period 1800 to 1600 BC, for example, the daily wage for a common laborer was enough to buy about 15 pounds of wheat. In Classical Athens in about 328 BC, the corresponding wage could buy about 24 pounds of wheat. In England in 1800 AD the wage was about 13 pounds of wheat.<ref name="Clark2007"/>{{rp|50}} In spite of the technological developments across these societies, the daily wage hardly varied. In Britain between 1200 and 1800, only relatively minor fluctuations from the mean (less than a factor of two) in real wages occurred. Following depopulation by the [[Black Death]] and other epidemics, real income in Britain peaked around 1450–1500 and began declining until the [[British Agricultural Revolution]].<ref>
{{cite book
|title= Agricultural Revolution in England: The transformation of the agrarian economy 1500–1850
|url= https://archive.org/details/isbn_9780521568593
|url-access= registration
|last=Overton
|first= Mark
|year=1996 |publisher =Cambridge University Press
|isbn= 978-0-521-56859-3
}}
</ref> Historian [[Walter Scheidel]] posits that waves of plague following the initial outbreak of the Black Death throughout Europe had a leveling effect that changed the ratio of land to labor, reducing the value of the former while boosting that of the latter, which lowered [[economic inequality]] by making employers and landowners less well off while improving the economic prospects and living standards of workers. He says that "the observed improvement in living standards of the laboring population was rooted in the suffering and premature death of tens of millions over the course of several generations." This leveling effect was reversed by a "demographic recovery that resulted in renewed [[population pressure]]."<ref>{{cite book | last = Scheidel| first = Walter | author-link =Walter Scheidel| title =The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century | publisher = [[Princeton University Press]]| year =2017 | isbn =978-0691165028|url=http://press.princeton.edu/titles/10921.html|pages=292–93, 304}}</ref>

[[Robert Fogel]] published a study of lifespans and nutrition from about a century before Malthus to the 19th century that examined European birth and death records, military and other records of height and weight that found significant stunted height and low body weight indicative of chronic hunger and malnutrition. He also found short lifespans that he attributed to chronic malnourishment which left people susceptible to disease. Lifespans, height and weight began to steadily increase in the UK and France after 1750. Fogel's findings are consistent with estimates of available food supply.<ref>{{cite book |title= The Escape from Hunger and Premature Death, 1700–2100|last=Fogel |first=Robert W.|author-link= Robert_Fogel|year=2004 |publisher= Cambridge University Press|location= London |isbn= 978-0-521-80878-1 }}</ref>

==Theory of breakout via technology==
{{See also|Industrial Revolution#Causes|British Agricultural Revolution}}

===Industrial Revolution===
Some researchers contend that a British breakout occurred due to technological improvements and structural change away from agricultural production, while coal, capital, and trade played a minor role.<ref>Tepper, Alexander and Karol J. Borowiecki. Accounting for Breakout in Britain: The Industrial Revolution through a Malthusian Lens (2013). Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 639. Available at: https://ideas.repec.org/p/fip/fednsr/639.html</ref> Economic historian [[Gregory Clark (economist)|Gregory Clark]], building on the insights of Galor and Moav,<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Voth|first=Hans-Joachim|date=2008|title=Clark's intellectual Sudoku|journal=European Review of Economic History|volume=12|issue=2|pages=149–155|doi=10.1017/S1361491608002190}}</ref> has argued, in his book ''[[A Farewell to Alms]]'', that a British breakout may have been caused by differences in reproduction rates among the rich and the poor (the rich were more likely to marry, tended to have more children, and, in a society where disease was rampant and childhood mortality at times approached 50%, upper-class children were more likely to survive to adulthood than poor children.) This in turn led to sustained "downward mobility": the descendants of the rich becoming more populous in British society and spreading [[middle-class values]] such as hard work and literacy.

===20th century===
[[File:Wars-Long-Run-military-civilian-fatalities.png|thumb|Global deaths in conflicts since the year 1400]]
[[Image:World population growth rates 1800-2005.png|thumb|right|200px|A chart of estimated annual growth rates in world population, 1800–2005. Rates before 1950 are annualized historical estimates from the US Census Bureau.<ref>https://www.census.gov/ipc/www/worldhis.html</ref> Red = USCB projections to 2025.]]
[[Image:Food production per capita.svg|thumb|right|200px|Growth in food production has historically been greater than the population growth. Food per person increased since 1961. The graph runs up to slightly past 2010.<ref>Data source: http://faostat3.fao.org/download/Q/QI/E, see graph metadata for further details.</ref>]]

After [[World War II]], [[mechanized agriculture]] produced a dramatic increase in productivity of agriculture and the [[Green Revolution]] greatly increased crop yields, expanding the world's food supply while lowering food prices. In response, the growth rate of the world's population accelerated rapidly, resulting in predictions by [[Paul R. Ehrlich]], Simon Hopkins,<ref>{{cite book|last = Hopkins|first = Simon|title = A Systematic Foray into the Future|publisher = Barker Books|year = 1966|pages = 513–69}}</ref> and many others of an imminent Malthusian catastrophe. However, populations of most developed countries grew slowly enough to be outpaced by gains in productivity.

By the early 21st century, many technologically-developed countries had passed through the [[demographic transition]], a complex social development encompassing a drop in [[total fertility rate]]s in response to various [[fertility factor (demography)|fertility factors]], including lower [[infant mortality]], increased [[urbanization]], and a wider availability of effective [[birth control]].

On the assumption that the [[demographic transition]] is now spreading from the developed countries to [[less developed countries]], the [[United Nations Population Fund]] estimates that human population may peak in the late 21st century rather than continue to grow until it has exhausted available resources.<ref name="UN">{{cite web|url=https://www.un.org/esa/population/publications/longrange2/WorldPop2300final.pdf|title=2004 UN Population Projections, 2004.}}</ref>

A 2004 study by a group of prominent economists and ecologists, including [[Kenneth Arrow]] and Paul Ehrlich<ref>Arrow, K., P. Dasgupta, L. Goulder, G. Daily, P. Ehrlich, G. Heal, S. Levin, K. Mäler, S. Schneider, D. Starrett and B. Walker, "Are We Consuming Too Much" ''Journal of Economic Perspectives'', 18(3), 147–72, 2004.</ref> suggests that the central concerns regarding sustainability have shifted from population growth to the consumption/savings ratio, due to shifts in population growth rates since the 1970s. Empirical estimates show that public policy (taxes or the establishment of more complete property rights) can promote more efficient consumption and investment that are sustainable in an ecological sense; that is, given the current (relatively low) population growth rate, the Malthusian catastrophe can be avoided by either a shift in consumer preferences{{example needed|date=September 2020}} or public policy that induces a similar shift.

==Criticism==
[[Karl Marx]] and [[Friedrich Engels]] argued that Malthus failed to recognize a crucial difference between humans and other species. In capitalist societies, as Engels put it, scientific and technological "progress is as unlimited and at least as rapid as that of population".<ref>Engels, Friedrich."Outlines of a Critique of Political Economy", ''Deutsch-Französische Jahrbücher'', 1844, p. 1.</ref> Marx argued, even more broadly, that the growth of both a human population ''in toto'' and the "[[relative surplus population]]" within it, occurred in direct proportion to [[Capital accumulation|accumulation]].<ref>Karl Marx (transl. Ben Fowkes), ''Capital Volume 1'', Harmondsworth, Penguin, 1976 (originally 1867), pp. 782–802.</ref>

[[Henry George]] in ''Progress and Poverty'' (1879) criticized Malthus's view that population growth was a cause of poverty, arguing that poverty was caused by the concentration of ownership of land and natural resources. George noted that humans are distinct from other species, because unlike most species humans can use their minds to leverage the reproductive forces of nature to their advantage. He wrote, "Both the jayhawk and the man eat chickens; but the more jayhawks, the fewer chickens, while the more men, the more chickens."<ref>{{Cite web|title=Progress and Poverty, Chapter 7|url=http://www.henrygeorge.org/pchp7.htm|website=www.henrygeorge.org|access-date=2020-05-17}}</ref>

D. E. C. Eversley observed that Malthus appeared unaware of the extent of industrialization, and either ignored or discredited the possibility that it could improve living conditions of the poorer classes.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Charles.|first=Eversley, David Edward|title=Social theories of fertility and the Malthusian debate|date=1959|publisher=Greenwood Press|isbn=9780837176284|location=Westport, Connecticut|oclc=1287575}}</ref>

[[Barry Commoner]] believed in ''The Closing Circle'' (1971) that technological progress will eventually reduce the demographic growth and environmental damage created by civilization. He also opposed coercive measures postulated by neo-malthusian movements of his time arguing that their cost will fall disproportionately on the low-income population who is struggling already.

[[Ester Boserup]] suggested that expanding population leads to agricultural intensification and development of more productive and less labor-intensive methods of farming. Thus, human population levels determines agricultural methods, rather than agricultural methods determining population.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Boserup|first=Ester|year=1966|title=The Conditions of Agricultural Growth. The Economics of Agrarian Change under Population Pressure|journal=Population|volume=21|issue=2|page=402|doi=10.2307/1528968|jstor=1528968}}</ref>

Environmentalist [[Stewart Brand]] summarized how the Malthusian predictions of ''[[The Population Bomb]]'' and ''[[The Limits to Growth]]'' failed to materialize due to radical changes in fertility:<ref>{{Cite book|last=Brand|first=Stewart|title=Whole Earth Discipline|year=2010|isbn=978-1843548164}}</ref>

{{Quote|text=The theory’s Malthusian premise has been proven wrong since 1963, when the rate of population growth reached a frightening 2 percent a year but then began dropping. The 1963 inflection point showed that the imagined soaring J-curve of human increase was instead a normal S-curve. The growth rate was leveling off. No one thought the growth rate might go negative and the population start shrinking in this century without an overshoot and crash, but that is what is happening.|author=[[Stewart Brand]]|title=|source=''[[Whole Earth Discipline]]''}}

Short-term trends, even on the scale of decades or centuries, cannot prove or disprove the existence of mechanisms promoting a Malthusian catastrophe over longer periods. However, due to the prosperity of a major fraction of the human population at the beginning of the 21st century, and the debatability of the predictions for [[ecological collapse]] made by [[Paul R. Ehrlich]] in the 1960s and 1970s, some people, such as economist [[Julian Lincoln Simon|Julian L. Simon]] and medical statistician [[Hans Rosling]] questioned its inevitability.<ref>Simon, Julian L, "[http://www.juliansimon.org/writings/Articles/REVOLUTI.txt More People, Greater Wealth, More Resources, Healthier Environment]", ''Economic Affairs: J. Inst. Econ. Affairs'', April 1994.</ref>{{See also|Simon–Ehrlich wager|The Ultimate Resource|Factfulness: Ten Reasons We're Wrong About the World – and Why Things Are Better Than You Think}}

[[Joseph Tainter]] asserts that science has diminishing marginal returns<ref>Tainter, Joseph. ''The Collapse of Complex Societies'', Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 2003.</ref>{{Incomplete short citation|date=October 2016}} and that scientific progress is becoming more difficult, harder to achieve, and more costly, which may reduce efficiency of the factors that prevented the Malthusian scenarios from happening in the past.

The view that a "breakout" from the Malthusian trap has led to an era of sustained economic growth is explored by "[[unified growth theory]]".<ref name="Galor (2005)" /><ref>{{Cite book|title=Unified Growth Theory|last=Galor|first=Oded|publisher=Princeton University Press|year=2011|location=Princeton}}</ref> One branch of unified growth theory is devoted to the interaction between human evolution and economic development. In particular, Oded Galor and Omer Moav argue that the forces of natural selection during the Malthusian epoch selected beneficial traits to the growth process and this growth enhancing change in the composition of human traits brought about the escape from the Malthusian trap, the demographic transition, and the take-off to modern growth.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Galor |first1=Oded |first2=Omer |last2=Moav |year=2002 |title=Natural Selection and The Origin of Economic Growth |journal=[[Quarterly Journal of Economics]] |volume=117 |issue=4 |pages=1133–91 |doi=10.1162/003355302320935007 |citeseerx=10.1.1.199.2634 }}</ref>

== See also ==
{{Portal|Economics}}
* [[2007–2008 world food price crisis]]
* [[Agricultural Involution]]
* [[Antinatalism]]
* [[Demographic trap]]
* [[Food technology]]
* [[Global catastrophic risk]]
* [[History of economic thought]]
* [[Human overpopulation]]
* [[Jevons's paradox]]
* [[Malthusianism]]
* [[Malthusian growth model]]
* [[Olduvai theory]]
* [[Overshoot (population)]]
* [[Peak phosphorus]]
* [[Political demography]]
* [[Population cycle]]
* [[Productivity-improving technologies]]
* [[r/K selection theory]]
* [[Spontaneous order]]
* [[Unified growth theory]]

==Notes==
{{Reflist|30em}}

==References==
{{Refbegin|}}
* Korotayev A., Malkov A., Khaltourina D. ''[https://www.academia.edu/32757085/Introduction_to_Social_Macrodynamics._Models_of_the_World_System_Development._Moscow_KomKniga_URSS_2006 Introduction to Social Macrodynamics: Compact Macromodels of the World System Growth.]'' Moscow: URSS, 2006. {{ISBN|5-484-00414-4}}
* Korotayev A., Malkov A., Khaltourina D. ''[https://www.academia.edu/22215616/Introduction_to_Social_Macrodynamics_Secular_Cycles_and_Millennial_Trends Introduction to Social Macrodynamics: Secular Cycles and Millennial Trends.]'' Moscow: URSS, 2006. {{ISBN|5-484-00559-0}} See especially Chapter 2 of this book
* Korotayev A. & Khaltourina D. ''[https://www.academia.edu/27503953/Introduction_to_Social_Macrodynamics_Secular_Cycles_and_Millennial_Trends_in_Africa Introduction to Social Macrodynamics: Secular Cycles and Millennial Trends in Africa.]'' Moscow: URSS, 2006. {{ISBN|5-484-00560-4}}
* {{Cite journal
| last = Malthus
| first = Thomas Robert
| author-link =Thomas Malthus
| year = 1798
| title =An Essay on the Principle of Population
| edition = First
| location = London
| url =http://www.esp.org/books/malthus/population/malthus.pdf
| access-date =29 March 2018 |journal=Electronic Scholarly Publishing Project}}
* [[Peter Turchin|Turchin, P.]], et al., eds. (2007). [http://edurss.ru/cgi-bin/db.pl?cp=&page=Book&id=53185&lang=en&blang=en&list=Found History & Mathematics: Historical Dynamics and Development of Complex Societies.] Moscow: KomKniga. {{ISBN|5-484-01002-0}}
* [https://www.academia.edu/15463657/A_Trap_At_The_Escape_From_The_Trap_Demographic_Structural_Factors_of_Political_Instability_in_Modern_Africa_and_West_Asia A Trap At The Escape From The Trap? Demographic-Structural Factors of Political Instability in Modern Africa and West Asia. ''Cliodynamics'' 2/2 (2011): 1–28].
*{{Cite book
| last = Malthus
| first = Thomas Robert
| author-link =Thomas Malthus
| year = 1826
| title =An Essay on the Principle of Population: A View of its Past and Present Effects on Human Happiness; with an Inquiry into Our Prospects Respecting the Future Removal or Mitigation of the Evils which It Occasions
| edition = Sixth
| location = London
| publisher =John Murray }}
*{{Cite book
| last = Pomeranz
| first = Kenneth
| year = 2000
| title =The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy
| isbn =978-0-691-09010-8
}}
*{{Cite book
| last = Rosen
| first = William
| year = 2010
| title =The Most Powerful Idea in the World
| location = New York
| publisher =Random House
| isbn =978-1-4000-6705-3
}}
{{Refend}}

==External links==
*[http://www.blupete.com/Literature/Biographies/Philosophy/Malthus.htm Essay on life of Thomas Malthus]
*[https://web.archive.org/web/20020202040555/http://www.ac.wwu.edu/~stephan/malthus/malthus.0.html Malthus' Essay on the Principle of Population]
*[http://www.daviddfriedman.com/Academic/Laissez-Faire_In_Popn/L_F_in_Population.html David Friedman's essay arguing against Malthus' conclusions]
*[https://www.un.org/popin/wdtrends.htm United Nations Population Division World Population Trends homepage]
{{Navboxes|list=
{{Human impact on the environment}}
{{Population}}
{{Population country lists}}
{{biological organisation}}
{{Globalization|state=autocollapse}}
{{Doomsday}}
}}

[[Category:Demographic economic problems]]
[[Category:Disaster preparedness]]
[[Category:Doomsday scenarios]]
[[Category:Energy economics]]
[[Category:Futures studies]]
[[Category:Human geography]]
[[Category:Human overpopulation]]
[[Category:Macroeconomic theories]]
[[Category:Theories of history]]

Latest revision as of 18:37, 22 January 2021

Redirect to:

  • From a merge: This is a redirect from a page that was merged into another page. This redirect was kept in order to preserve the edit history of this page after its content was merged into the content of the target page. Please do not remove the tag that generates this text (unless the need to recreate content on this page has been demonstrated) or delete this page.