Fungibility

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by 86.133.21.82 (talk) at 07:08, 1 May 2006. The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

You must add a |reason= parameter to this Cleanup template – replace it with {{Cleanup|reason=<Fill reason here>}}, or remove the Cleanup template.
Fungibility is a measure of how easily one example of a good may be exchanged for another example of the same good. Much of this article mistakenly confuses fungibility with liquidity. A good is liquid (or tradeable) if it can be exchanged for another different good. Fungible and tradeable are not the same. The remainder of this article is fundamentally incorrect in this respect.

Many commodities that are fungible, also tend to be liquid. For example, gold is fungible and highly liquid, while diamonds are not fungible and have lower liquidity.

Fungibility in Economics

Fungibility is an attribute of an economic good. In a barter economy commerce is slowed because each exchange requires searching out a partner who is willing to exchange a good you want for a good you have. Such deals are easier to make if you posess highly fungible goods. Fungiblity is not the only quality of a good but it is corrolated with some key attributes. For example nonperishable, easily measured, widely useful, goods of high value density are typically more rather than less fungible. Goods with a reasonably stable supply, so their value is dependable, are more fungible. Certain commodities are traditional examples of highly fungible goods such as tobacco, grain, or precious metals. Barter economies often rendevous around one or more highly fungible goods.

Fungibility is a widely useful term for getting at the nature of exchange; thus it is often used in fields surprisingly distant from economics. Below are some examples. These examples illustrate that fungiblity is not always a desirable attribute. For example you might give a child a gift certificate rather than cash so as to limit her options to more wholesome purchases.

Fungiblity in finance

In finance, fungibility refers to the ability of one security to be easily converted into another. Stocks listed on several stock exchanges are more fungible than those listed only on one. Stocks with high dependable trading volumes are more liquid than those that are rarely traded.

Checks, a currency substitute, are less fungible than cash. The international and national interbank check clearing systems exist to link those two currency systems. Numerous exchange systems (currency, commodity, clearing houses) exist to resolve these differences in fungiblity.

One way to look at the function of any marketplace is as a means to make the goods moving through it more fungible.

Fungibility in relations

Discussion about exchanges between parties is nearly impossible to separate from discussions about the relationships between those parties. Parents will often limit what their children may spend their allowance on. Employers will limit what their employees may purchase when traveling. Fungiblity provides one a way to discuss such examples. For example shop keepers are sometimes willing to sell you a gift certificate at a discount because it creates a marketing relationship.

Fungibility gives rise to a persistent puzzle of how to retain control after funding an activity. Consider the example of charitable giving. Donors would often prefer to earmark their donations for a particular purpose. That frustrates the recipents who would prefer to retain their freedom of action. Both sides can find this frustrating. The donor can be frustrated to discover the money he gave for a particular purpose was spent as he desired, but yet the organization reduced it's usual level of funding for that purpose shifting funds to other activities. This puzzle arises in all funding situations. For example international development, venture capital, and children's lunch money.

Fungibility and open/closed systems

Beyond simple relationships fungibility can give rise to puzzles around groups. Groups may take the decision to reduce fungiblity for planning purposes. For example: annual budgeting in hierarchical organizations reduces the organization's ability to move funds across the organization. A group may place tight controls on the fungiblity around their periphery. For example in a nation that provides numerous benefits for its citizens, currency controls are needed to collect the taxes that support those benefits, particularly at the nation's borders.

Fungibility can make it difficult to get a clear picture of what's really going on. Consider medical debt where conversion of medical debt into a different kind of debt, such as credit card debt, will mask the real amount of debt's origin from health care costs. For instance, an individual might pay for his or her emergency-room visit on a credit card, and therefore convert health care-generated debt into credit-card debt. The fungibility of medical debt is oftentimes more insidious, however. In many cases, individuals are forced to pay steep health plan deductibles as well as out-of-pocket co-payments to receive care. These high medical costs drive many people to delay paying other bills, like mortgage or utility payments, which cause them to incur debt.

Fungibility in science

In Does God Play Dice? The New Mathematics of Chaos, the mathematician Ian Stewart argues that fungibility applies to science as well. The example he uses is that subatomic particle theory is fungible when studying molecules "provided it led to the same general feature of a replicable molecule."

Another example is the concept of mass, either gravitational or inertial mass. Mass is fungible in all observationally consistent theories of gravitation. All compositions of matter fall identically in vacuum, including binding energies.

See also