Darwin central business district and Search and matching theory (economics): Difference between pages

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Difference between pages)
Content deleted Content added
No edit summary
 
 
Line 1: Line 1:
In [[macroeconomics]], '''matching theory''', also known as '''search and matching theory''',
{{otheruses4|the area with the postcode 0800 in the [[Northern Territory]] known as Darwin|the city and metropolitan area, also known as Darwin|Darwin, Northern Territory}}
is a mathematical framework describing the formation of mutually beneficial relationships
{{Infobox Australian Place
over time. The key element that distinguishes matching theory from other approaches to
| name = Darwin
[[Model (macroeconomics)|macroeconomic modelling]] is the presence of a '''matching function'''.
| image = Darwin skyline.jpg
| caption = Looking towards the CBD from East Point
| state = nt
| type = suburb
| lga = City of Darwin
| city = [[Darwin, Northern Territory|Darwin]]
| est = 1869
| postcode = 0800
| pop = 2,484 (2006) <ref name="abs">{{Census 2006 AUS | id = SSC71046 | name = Darwin City (State Suburb) | accessdate = 2008-06-15 | quick = on}}</ref>
| fedgov = [[Division of Solomon]]
| stategov = [[Electoral division of Port Darwin|Port Darwin]]
| propval = $1,875,000 <ref>[http://www.domain.com.au/public/SuburbProfile.aspx?searchTerm=Darwin&mode=buy#mapanchor Domain.com.au Suburb Report - Darwin] (Nov 06) Accessed [[15 June]] [[2008]]</ref>
| near-nw = [[The Gardens, Northern Territory|The Gardens]]
| near-n = [[Stuart Park, Northern Territory|Stuart Park]]
| near-ne =
| near-w = [[Larrakeyah, Northern Territory|Larrakeyah]]
| near-e = ''Francis Bay''
| near-sw =
| near-s = ''Darwin Harbour''
| near-se =
}}


Matching theory has been especially influential in [[labor economics]],
The '''Darwin city centre''' (referred to as ''Darwin City'' or ''The CBD'' (Central Business District) is a locality surrounded by [[Darwin, Northern Territory|metropolitan Darwin]] which comprises the original settlement, the central business district, parkland and other built-up areas. It is the oldest part of Darwin and includes many of the city's important institutions and landmarks, such as [[Parliament House, Darwin|Parliament]], [[Government House, Darwin|Government House]], the [[Northern Territory Supreme Court]], [[Bicentennial Park (Darwin)|Bicentennial Park]] and the [[George Brown Darwin Botanic Gardens]]. The city centre is located in the [[Local Government Areas in Australia|local government area]]s of the [[City of Darwin]].
where it has been used to describe the formation of new jobs, as well as to describe other
human relationships like [[marriage]]. Matching theory is closely related to an earlier framework
called [[search theory]] which is somewhat more commonly applied in [[microeconomics]].


One of the founders of matching theory is [[Dale T. Mortensen]] of [[Northwestern University]].
Although the city centre is one of the most developed areas of Darwin, demographically it is one of the less densely populated, due to its core being commercial.
A textbook treatment of the matching approach to labor markets is [[Christopher A. Pissarides]]'
book ''Equilibrium Unemployment Theory''.<ref>Pissarides, Christopher (2000), ''Equilibrium Unemployment Theory'', 2nd ed. MIT Press, ISBN 0262161877.</ref>


==History==
{{see|History of Darwin}}
The first [[United Kingdom|British]] person to see Darwin harbour appears to have been Lieutenant [[John Lort Stokes]] of [[HMS Beagle|HMS ''Beagle'']] on [[9 September]] [[1839]]. The ship's captain, Commander [[John Clements Wickham]], named the port after [[Charles Darwin]], the British naturalist who had sailed with them both on the earlier [[second voyage of HMS Beagle|second expedition of the ''Beagle'']].


==The matching function==
In the early 1870s, Darwin felt the effects of a [[Australian gold rushes|gold rush]] at [[Pine Creek, Northern Territory|Pine Creek]] after employees of the [[Australian Overland Telegraph Line]] found gold while digging holes for telegraph poles.
A matching function is a mathematical relationship
that describes the formation of new relationships (also called 'matches')
from unmatched [[Agent (economics)|agents]] of the appropriate types.
For example, in the context of job formation, matching functions are sometimes assumed
to have the following [[Cobb-Douglas production function|'Cobb-Douglas']] form:


:<math>m_t \; = \; M(u_t,v_t) \; = \; \mu u_t^a v_t^b</math>
On [[5 February]] [[1869]], [[George Goyder]], the Surveyor-General of South Australia, established a small settlement of 135 people at Port Darwin. Goyder named the settlement [[Palmerston, Northern Territory|Palmerston]], after the [[Prime Minister of the United Kingdom|British Prime Minister]] [[Henry Temple, 3rd Viscount Palmerston|Lord Palmerston]]. In 1870, the first poles for the [[Australian Overland Telegraph Line|Overland Telegraph]] were erected in Darwin, connecting Australia to the rest of the world. The discovery of gold at [[Pine Creek, Northern Territory|Pine Creek]] in the 1880s further boosted the young colony's development. Upon Commonwealth administration in 1911, Darwin became the city's official name.


where <math>\,\mu\,</math>, <math>\,a\,</math>, and <math>\,b\,</math> are positive constants.
==Geography==
In this equation, <math>\,u_t\,</math> represents the number of unemployed
[[Image:Darwin Panorama.jpg|right|thumb|200px|View of Darwin CBD from the [[Stuart Highway]]]]
job seekers in the economy at a given time <math>\,t\,</math>, and <math>\,v_t\,</math>
The city centre is bordered by [[Daly Street]] to the north and extends east to the [[Stuart Highway]] [[McMinn Street]] to the east which borders [[Stuart Park, Northern Territory|Stuart Park]]. The border extends and east along Darwin Harbour it extends South the the [[Darwin Convention Centre|Darwin Waterfront]] and to the [[Darwin Convention Centre]]. It extends West along the Esplande and [[Bicentennial Park (Darwin)|Bicentennial Park]].<ref>[http://www.nt.gov.au/lands/lis/placenames/origins/darwincity.shtml City of Darwin streets and roads]</ref>
is the number of [[Vacancy (economics)|vacant jobs]] firms are trying to fill.
The number of new relationships (matches) created (per unit of time) is given by
<math>\,m_t\,</math>.


A matching function is in general analogous to a [[production function]].
==Demographics==
But whereas a production function usually represents the production of
Darwin has one of the fastest growing residential populations in Australia. The CBD recorded a 5.1 per cent increase in population in 2007.<ref>[http://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/abs@.nsf/Lookup/3218.0Main%20Features42006-07?opendocument&tabname=Summary&prodno=3218.0&issue=2006-07&num=&view=#NORTHERN%20TERRITORY ABS Regional Population Growth]</ref>
goods and services from inputs like labor and capital, a matching
function represents the formation of new relationships from the pools of available
unmatched individuals. Estimates of the matching function suggest that it has
[[constant returns to scale]], that is, <math>a+b\approx 1</math>.<ref>Barbara
Petrongolo and Christopher Pissarides (2001), 'Looking into the black box: a survey of the matching function'. ''Journal of Economic Literature'' 39 (2), pp. 390-431.</ref>


If the fraction of jobs that separate (due to firing, quits, and so forth)
==References==
from one period to the next is <math>\,\delta\,</math>,
{{reflist}}
then to calculate the change in employment from one period to the next we must
add the formation of new matches and subtract off the separation of old matches.
A period may be treated as a week, a month, a quarter, or some other convenient period of time,
depending on the data under consideration. (For simplicity, we are ignoring the entry
of new workers into the labor force, and death or retirement of old workers,
but these issues can be accounted for as well.)
Suppose we write the number of workers employed in period <math>\,t\,</math> as <math>\,n_t=L_t-u_t\,</math>,
where <math>\,L_t\,</math> is the [[labor force]] in period <math>\,t\,</math>.
Then given the matching function described above,
the dynamics of employment over time would be given by


:<math>n_{t+1} \; = \mu u_t^a v_t^b + (1-\delta)n_t</math>
{{City of Darwin suburbs}}


For simplicity, many studies treat <math>\,\delta\,</math> as a fixed constant.
{{coord|12|27|41.44|S|130|50|30.83|E|region:AU-NT_type:city(109,419)|display=title}}
But the fraction of workers separating per period of time can be determined
[[Endogeneity (economics)|endogenously]] if we assume that the value of being matched
varies over time for each worker-firm pair (due, for example, to changes
in [[productivity]]).<ref>Dale Mortensen and Christopher Pissarides (1994),
'Job creation and job destruction in the theory of unemployment.'
''Review of Economic Studies'' 61, pp. 397-415.</ref>

==Applications==
Matching theory has been applied in many economic contexts, including:
*Formation of jobs, from unemployed workers and vacancies opened by firms
*Formation of marriages, from unmatched men and women
*Allocation of loans from banks to entrepreneurs
*Sales occurring when sellers and buyers meet

==Controversy==
Matching theory has been widely accepted as one of the best available descriptions
of the frictions in the labor market, but some economists
have recently questioned its quantitative accuracy. While unemployment exhibits large
fluctuations over the [[business cycle]], [[Robert Shimer]] has demonstrated that
standard versions of matching models predict much smaller fluctuations in
unemployment.<ref>Robert Shimer (2005), 'The cyclical behavior of equilibrium
unemployment and vacancies'. 95 (1), pp. 25-49.''American Economic Review''</ref>

==See also==
* [[Search theory]]
* [[Labor economics]]
* [[Monetary economics]]

==References==
<references />


[[Category:Central business districts]]
[[Category:Macroeconomics]]
[[Category:Visitor attractions in Darwin]]
[[Category:Labor economics]]

Revision as of 12:33, 10 October 2008

In macroeconomics, matching theory, also known as search and matching theory, is a mathematical framework describing the formation of mutually beneficial relationships over time. The key element that distinguishes matching theory from other approaches to macroeconomic modelling is the presence of a matching function.

Matching theory has been especially influential in labor economics, where it has been used to describe the formation of new jobs, as well as to describe other human relationships like marriage. Matching theory is closely related to an earlier framework called search theory which is somewhat more commonly applied in microeconomics.

One of the founders of matching theory is Dale T. Mortensen of Northwestern University. A textbook treatment of the matching approach to labor markets is Christopher A. Pissarides' book Equilibrium Unemployment Theory.[1]


The matching function

A matching function is a mathematical relationship that describes the formation of new relationships (also called 'matches') from unmatched agents of the appropriate types. For example, in the context of job formation, matching functions are sometimes assumed to have the following 'Cobb-Douglas' form:

where , , and are positive constants. In this equation, represents the number of unemployed job seekers in the economy at a given time , and is the number of vacant jobs firms are trying to fill. The number of new relationships (matches) created (per unit of time) is given by .

A matching function is in general analogous to a production function. But whereas a production function usually represents the production of goods and services from inputs like labor and capital, a matching function represents the formation of new relationships from the pools of available unmatched individuals. Estimates of the matching function suggest that it has constant returns to scale, that is, .[2]

If the fraction of jobs that separate (due to firing, quits, and so forth) from one period to the next is , then to calculate the change in employment from one period to the next we must add the formation of new matches and subtract off the separation of old matches. A period may be treated as a week, a month, a quarter, or some other convenient period of time, depending on the data under consideration. (For simplicity, we are ignoring the entry of new workers into the labor force, and death or retirement of old workers, but these issues can be accounted for as well.) Suppose we write the number of workers employed in period as , where is the labor force in period . Then given the matching function described above, the dynamics of employment over time would be given by

For simplicity, many studies treat as a fixed constant. But the fraction of workers separating per period of time can be determined endogenously if we assume that the value of being matched varies over time for each worker-firm pair (due, for example, to changes in productivity).[3]

Applications

Matching theory has been applied in many economic contexts, including:

  • Formation of jobs, from unemployed workers and vacancies opened by firms
  • Formation of marriages, from unmatched men and women
  • Allocation of loans from banks to entrepreneurs
  • Sales occurring when sellers and buyers meet

Controversy

Matching theory has been widely accepted as one of the best available descriptions of the frictions in the labor market, but some economists have recently questioned its quantitative accuracy. While unemployment exhibits large fluctuations over the business cycle, Robert Shimer has demonstrated that standard versions of matching models predict much smaller fluctuations in unemployment.[4]

See also

References

  1. ^ Pissarides, Christopher (2000), Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, 2nd ed. MIT Press, ISBN 0262161877.
  2. ^ Barbara Petrongolo and Christopher Pissarides (2001), 'Looking into the black box: a survey of the matching function'. Journal of Economic Literature 39 (2), pp. 390-431.
  3. ^ Dale Mortensen and Christopher Pissarides (1994), 'Job creation and job destruction in the theory of unemployment.' Review of Economic Studies 61, pp. 397-415.
  4. ^ Robert Shimer (2005), 'The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies'. 95 (1), pp. 25-49.American Economic Review