Neostructuralism (economic theory)

from Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Neostructuralism is an approach to development economics that emerged in 1990 . In Latin America, it has replaced the neoliberal approach that had prevailed since the 1980s in the sense of the Washington Consensus as the predominant development economics approach.

history

The content-related forerunner of neostructuralism was structuralism . Structural economic policy was largely promoted by the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean CEPAL . Structuralism was dominant from the 1960s to the mid-1980s.

The structuralist economic policy was replaced in the 1980s by a phase of economic policy based on the Washington Consensus , which lasted until around the year 2000 . The economic policy also propagated by the World Bank was seen as a “neoliberal” inspired policy imposed on the South American countries from abroad. It resulted in below-average economic growth compared to earlier phases and proved to be very unpopular with the population.

Since the mid-1980s, Fernando Fajnzylber, an intellectual pioneer of neostructuralism , urged the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean ( CEPAL ) to adopt a new development strategy. The publication of the influential publication Transformación Productiva con Equidad (economic structural change and social equality) in 1989 is considered to be the birth of neostructuralism . Starting with the election of Ricardo Lagos in Chile (2000), a number of center-left governments were elected in Latin America, which passed to the economic policy of neo-structuralism.

Demarcation

The following table by Fernando Ignacio Leiva compares the economic policy paradigms of structuralism , neoliberalism in the sense of the Washington Consensus and neostructuralism:

Paradigms Structuralism (1950–1970) Neoliberalism in the sense of the Washington Consensus (1973 to today) Neostructuralism (1990 to today)
Motto Structural change Structural adjustment Productivity-enhancing transformation and social justice
target Modernization through industrialization Modernization through privatization Modernization through globalization
Development policy Political will, state intervention rationalized through the planning process Spontaneous result of the efforts of market participants, driven by the free price allocation mechanism A well thought-out process in which the state and society concentrate their forces on a dynamic contribution to world trade
Initiator of the development Country market Technical progress through dynamic incorporation into world trade
Obstacles World trade reproduces the center-periphery asymmetries. Historically grown structures deform the market process. State intervention stifles private initiative and shackles the allocation mechanism of the market. Overvalued currencies make export opportunities worse. In developing and emerging countries, uncoordinated market mechanisms mean that competitiveness is sought more through low wages and currency devaluations than through productivity and innovation progress.
tasks of the state Reform structures, manage capital accumulation, develop key industries. Guarantee the minimum requirements for the functioning of the market (enforce contracts, protect property, etc.), reduce the social network. Promote competitiveness on the world market (cluster, public-private partnership). Promote adaptability and skills of workers. Strengthen social cohesion.
Social conflict The state absorbs the pressure of social groups. Repression of the trade unions. Trust in the trickle-down effect . Cut subsidies. Channeling social conflicts or subordinating them to the goal of bringing them into world trade.
result The economy is subordinate to politics. Politics is subordinate to economy. Politics and culture have to be adapted to the demands of globalization.

Web links

Individual evidence

  1. ^ Fernando Ignacio Leiva: Toward a Critique of Latin American Neostructuralism. In: William C. Smith, Laura Gomez-Mera: Market, State, and Society in Contemporary Latin America , Blackwell Publ., 2010, ISBN 978-1444335255 , page 33
  2. ^ Joseph L. Love: The Rise and Decline of Economic Structuralism in Latin America. In: Latin American Research Review. Vol. 40 No. 3 (2005), pp. 100-125. P. 100.
  3. ^ Joseph L. Love: The Rise and Decline of Economic Structuralism in Latin America. In: Latin American Research Review. Vol. 40 No. 3 (2005), pp. 100–125, here: p. 107.
  4. ^ Justin Yifu Lin, New Structural Economics, A Framework For Rethinking Development . (PDF; 345 kB) page 10
  5. Fernando Ignacio Leiva, Latin American Neostructuralism: The Contradictions of Post-Neoliberal Development , University of Minnesota Press, 2008, ISBN 978-0816653287 , p. 4
  6. Fernando Ignacio Leiva, Toward a Critique of Latin American Neostructuralism in: William C. Smith, Laura Gomez-Mera, Market, State, and Society in Contemporary Latin America , Blackwell Publ., 2010, ISBN 978-1444335255 , page 33
  7. Fernando Ignacio Leiva, Toward a Critique of Latin American Neostructuralism in: William C. Smith, Laura Gomez-Mera, Market, State, and Society in Contemporary Latin America , Blackwell Publ., 2010, ISBN 978-1444335255 , page 35