Charles Comte: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
→‎Sources: cu, renamed ext links.
m Disambiguating links to Charles X (link changed to Charles X of France) using DisamAssist.
(32 intermediate revisions by 25 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|French lawyer, journalist and political writer (1782–1837)}}
'''Charles Comte''' (1782-1837) (François-Charles-Louis Comte) was a French lawyer, journalist and political writer. In 1814 he founded, with [[Charles Dunoyer]], [[Le Censeur‎]], the liberal journal. In 1820, he was found guilty of attacks against the King and went into exile in Switzerland where as professor of natural law, he taught at the University of Lausanne in Switzerland.<ref name ="JLS">[http://mises.org/journals/jls/1_3/1_3_1.pdf Liggio, Leonard, P.'' Charlles Dunoyer and French Classical Liberalism'' (1977) Journal of LIbertarian Studies, Vol. 1. No. 3. Pergamon Press, p. 163] Retrieved 14 September 2010</ref> Following comments made by Fredric Jean Witt, a revolutionary, to the Bavarian police, and an intervention by the French police, Comte was forced to leave Switzerland.<ref name ="JLS"/> He took refuge in England for 18 months where he became acquainted with [[Jeremy Bentham]], and in 1825 he returned to France and began contributing to the ''Revue Americaine''.<ref name ="JLS"/> In 1827 he published ''Traité de législation'' (4 volumes, in-8) (A Treaty of law) which outlined laws governing the development of companies and the reasons why development might be held back. The book established his reputation and earned him a [[Montyon Prizes|Montyon Prize]]. As an economist he followed the doctrines of [[Jean-Baptiste Say]] whose daughter he married. He was active in the opposition which led to the July Revolution of 1830 and was elected a deputy in the [[Sarthe]] in 1831 and again in 1834.<ref name ="JLS"/> In 1832 he was elected to the [[Académie des Sciences Morales et Politiques]].
'''François-Charles-Louis Comte''' (1782–1837) was a French lawyer, journalist and political writer.

== Biography ==
In 1814, Comte, along with [[Charles Dunoyer]], founded with ''[[Le Censeur]]'', a liberal journal. In 1820, he was found guilty of attacks against the King and went into exile in Switzerland, where as professor of natural law he taught at the University of Lausanne in Switzerland.<ref name="JLS">[https://mises.org/journals/jls/1_3/1_3_1.pdf Liggio, Leonard, P.'' Charlles Dunoyer and French Classical Liberalism'' (1977) Journal of Libertarian Studies, Vol. 1. No. 3. Pergamon Press, p. 163]. Retrieved 14 September 2010.</ref> Following comments made by Fredric Jean Witt, a revolutionary, to the Bavarian police and an intervention by the French police, Comte was forced to leave Switzerland.<ref name="JLS"/> Comte took refuge in England for eighteen months where he became acquainted with [[Jeremy Bentham]], but returned to France in 1825 and began contributing to the ''Revue Americaine''.<ref name="JLS"/> In 1827, he published ''Traité de législation'' (''A Treatise on Law''; 4 volumes, in-8) which outlined laws governing the development of companies and the reasons why development might be held back. The book established his reputation and earned him a [[Montyon Prizes|Montyon Prize]].{{Citation needed|date=March 2021}} As an economist, he followed the doctrines of [[Jean-Baptiste Say]] whose daughter he married. Comte was active in the opposition which led to the [[July Revolution of 1830]] as he refused to pay taxes until [[Charles X of France|Charles X]] revoked a series anti-liberal decrees and was elected a deputy in the [[Sarthe]] in 1831 and again in 1834.<ref name="JLS" /> In 1832, he was elected to the [[Académie des Sciences Morales et Politiques]].{{Citation needed|date=March 2021}}


== Quotes ==
== Quotes ==
Some quotes which give a good feel for his work:<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.onpower.org/quotes/c.html|title=The Independent Institute &#124; C Quotes|publisher=On Power|accessdate=8 October 2010}}</ref> <blockquote>Newspapers could be of great utility, but the great importance which they attach to simple literary discussions, the indifference they have for anything which smacks of legislation, and the habit they have acquired of adulation (of the government), prevents one from hoping that they will busy themselves in enlightening citizens of their true interests. What they do not do, I propose to undertake.<ref>''Journal des économistes'', June 1846, vol. XIV, p. 271.</ref></blockquote>
<blockquote>The revolution which brought about in France the fall of the Imperial government, without changing at all the direction of my ideas, forced me to choose a means of publication different from that which I had at first proposed. It seemed to me that in treating in succession questions of politics or legislation which circumstances threw up I would achieve my aim most surely and promptly. Observations applied to those events which one witnesses have greater impact than those observations made from a distance. The freedom to publicly present one's opinions, which the previous government had completely destroyed, was eventually proclaimed and it was imperative to take advantage of it. Because it is the same of liberty and power, one runs the great risk of losing it if one does not seize it the very instant when it appears.<ref>''Traité de législation'', 3rd ed, p. xiii.</ref></blockquote>


An opponent of monarchy, Comte nevertheless saw how even a democratic government retained certain things in common with the old order, saying: <blockquote>What must never be lost sight of is that a public functionary, in his capacity as functionary, produces absolutely nothing; that, on the contrary, he exists only on the products of the industrious class; and that he can consume nothing that has not been taken from the producers.</blockquote>
Some quotes give a good feel for his work.<ref>http://www.onpower.org/quotes/c.html</ref>
“Newspapers could be of great utility, but the great importance which they attach to simple literary discussions, the indifference they have for anything which smacks of legislation, and the habit they have acquired of adulation (of the government), prevents one from hoping that they will busy themselves in enlightening citizens of their true interests. What they do not do, I propose to undertake.” (''Journal des économistes'', June 1846, vol. XIV, p.271)

“The revolution which brought about in France the fall of the Imperial government, without changing at all the direction of my ideas, forced me to choose a means of publication different from that which I had at first proposed. It seemed to me that in treating in succession questions of politics or legislation which circumstances threw up I would achieve my aim most surely and promptly. Observations applied to those events which one witnesses have greater impact than those observations made from a distance. The freedom to publicly present one's opinions, which the previous government had completely destroyed, was eventually proclaimed and it was imperative to take advantage of it. Because it is the same of liberty and power, one runs the great risk of losing it if one does not seize it the very instant when it appears.” (''Traité de législation'', 3rd ed, p. xiii)


== References ==
== References ==
{{Reflist}}
{{reflist}}

==Further reading==
* {{cite encyclopedia|last=Hart|first=David|authorlink=|editor-first=Ronald|editor-last=Hamowy|editor-link=Ronald Hamowy|encyclopedia=The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism|title=Comte, Charles (1782–1837)|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=yxNgXs3TkJYC|year=2008 |publisher=[[SAGE Publishing|Sage]]; [[Cato Institute]]|location=Thousand Oaks, CA|doi=10.4135/9781412965811.n56|isbn=978-1-4129-6580-4|oclc=750831024|lccn=2008009151|pages=86–87|quote=}}


== External links ==
== External links ==
* http://homepage.mac.com/dmhart/FrenchClassicalLiberals/Comte/Comte-BioBibliography.html
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20111106021448/http://homepage.mac.com/dmhart/FrenchClassicalLiberals/Comte/Comte-BioBibliography.html Charles Comte Bio and Biblio]
{{Portalbar|Economics|France|Liberalism|Libertarianism|Politics}}
{{authority control}}


{{DEFAULTSORT:Comte, Charles}}
{{DEFAULTSORT:Comte, Charles}}
[[Category:French liberal theorists]]
[[Category:French economists]]
[[Category:French economists]]
[[Category:French libertarians]]
[[Category:French tax resisters]]
[[Category:French tax resisters]]
[[Category:Members of the Académie des sciences morales et politiques]]
[[Category:Members of the Académie des sciences morales et politiques]]
[[Category:1782 births]]

[[Category:1837 deaths]]
[[fr:Charles Comte (1782-1837)]]

Revision as of 11:07, 10 March 2024

François-Charles-Louis Comte (1782–1837) was a French lawyer, journalist and political writer.

Biography

In 1814, Comte, along with Charles Dunoyer, founded with Le Censeur, a liberal journal. In 1820, he was found guilty of attacks against the King and went into exile in Switzerland, where as professor of natural law he taught at the University of Lausanne in Switzerland.[1] Following comments made by Fredric Jean Witt, a revolutionary, to the Bavarian police and an intervention by the French police, Comte was forced to leave Switzerland.[1] Comte took refuge in England for eighteen months where he became acquainted with Jeremy Bentham, but returned to France in 1825 and began contributing to the Revue Americaine.[1] In 1827, he published Traité de législation (A Treatise on Law; 4 volumes, in-8) which outlined laws governing the development of companies and the reasons why development might be held back. The book established his reputation and earned him a Montyon Prize.[citation needed] As an economist, he followed the doctrines of Jean-Baptiste Say whose daughter he married. Comte was active in the opposition which led to the July Revolution of 1830 as he refused to pay taxes until Charles X revoked a series anti-liberal decrees and was elected a deputy in the Sarthe in 1831 and again in 1834.[1] In 1832, he was elected to the Académie des Sciences Morales et Politiques.[citation needed]

Quotes

Some quotes which give a good feel for his work:[2]

Newspapers could be of great utility, but the great importance which they attach to simple literary discussions, the indifference they have for anything which smacks of legislation, and the habit they have acquired of adulation (of the government), prevents one from hoping that they will busy themselves in enlightening citizens of their true interests. What they do not do, I propose to undertake.[3]

The revolution which brought about in France the fall of the Imperial government, without changing at all the direction of my ideas, forced me to choose a means of publication different from that which I had at first proposed. It seemed to me that in treating in succession questions of politics or legislation which circumstances threw up I would achieve my aim most surely and promptly. Observations applied to those events which one witnesses have greater impact than those observations made from a distance. The freedom to publicly present one's opinions, which the previous government had completely destroyed, was eventually proclaimed and it was imperative to take advantage of it. Because it is the same of liberty and power, one runs the great risk of losing it if one does not seize it the very instant when it appears.[4]

An opponent of monarchy, Comte nevertheless saw how even a democratic government retained certain things in common with the old order, saying:

What must never be lost sight of is that a public functionary, in his capacity as functionary, produces absolutely nothing; that, on the contrary, he exists only on the products of the industrious class; and that he can consume nothing that has not been taken from the producers.

References

  1. ^ a b c d Liggio, Leonard, P. Charlles Dunoyer and French Classical Liberalism (1977) Journal of Libertarian Studies, Vol. 1. No. 3. Pergamon Press, p. 163. Retrieved 14 September 2010.
  2. ^ "The Independent Institute | C Quotes". On Power. Retrieved 8 October 2010.
  3. ^ Journal des économistes, June 1846, vol. XIV, p. 271.
  4. ^ Traité de législation, 3rd ed, p. xiii.

Further reading

External links