Low interest rate policy

from Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Key interest rates of the Federal Reserve System (in blue) and the European Central Bank (in red) from 1999 to 2015: low interest rate policy from 2008

Low interest rate policy , also colloquially known as “cheap money policy”, is the entirety of the monetary policy measures of a central bank , which are intended to lower the general level of interest rates (market rates) in a currency area to a low level or to keep them there. The most important financial instrument for this is the key interest rate , the lowering of which enables the central bank to enable commercial banks to agree lower interest rates on their loans to companies and households. This type of lowering of the cost of capital is intended to stimulate investments and thus the economy of an economy.

The purchase of government bonds or private securities ( quantitative easing ) provides a central bank with another instrument for lowering interest rates ; Helicopter money has been discussed as an additional instrument since 2015 . Since the interest rates on government bonds fall, the public sector can finance its budget deficits more cheaply . At the expense of the central bank balance sheet , national debt is becoming “more bearable”, as a result of which measures in the area of restrictive fiscal policy are abandoned or an expansionary fiscal policy is facilitated.

A particularly extreme example of such a course is shown by Japan's monetary policy since the early 1990s or since 2013 ( Abenomics ). Since the financial crisis in 2007 , the European Central Bank has also been on this course of expansionary monetary policy via securities purchase programs , as is the US Federal Reserve System at the moment. In 2016, the low interest rate policy with interest rates little over, at or even below zero was still considered “unconventional”.

If the market interest rate is kept at or near zero by an interest rate policy, it is also referred to as a zero interest rate policy . If a key interest rate - such as the deposit rate - is below zero, the terms negative interest rate policy or minus interest rate policy are also used.

Risks

A sustained low interest rate policy also entails risks for a financial system : With the lowering of the general interest rate level, investors only achieve a low return on their saved capital ( savings deposits , time deposits ), often with an interest gain below the inflation rate . In extreme cases, there is even a burden in the form of a so-called negative interest rate . Due to the low interest rate policy, the value storage function of money is reduced . In this context, other asset classes take on this function of storing value, i.e. assets such as real estate (“ concrete gold ”), stocks and precious metals , especially gold . In conjunction with inflation, negative, zero and low interest rates result in a “ financial repression ” of savings and time deposits that are traditionally held by members of lower income groups with little financial knowledge, especially for the purposes of retirement provision . Investors therefore increasingly prefer an asset allocation to assets such as real estate, stocks and precious metals such as gold as an investment . As a result, the market value of the assets can significantly exceed the intrinsic value . Speculative bubbles , such as real estate bubbles , can occur or become stronger. Decline due to the reduction in the general level of interest rates, the returns from savings deposits, time deposits and life insurance , can business models appropriate financial companies are themselves at risk, may these companies. In addition, there is a risk that states and other regional authorities, institutions and corporations under public law, companies and private households will become over - indebted in a low-interest environment . Loan- financed statism is promoted. Another danger of a low interest rate environment is that riskier investment strategies will be pursued as a result of the easier lending process (“search for yield”). Money flows into risky and more often unprofitable projects and companies (“ zombie companies ”). In this way, non-performing loans and the requirement for provisions are increasing , as is the tendency to securitize the loans in toxic financial products . In other words: the credit risk increases , capital is misallocated , the subprime market grows, “ zombie banks ” arise , a contagion effect occurs. These risks can lead to banking and financial crises as well as currency and sovereign debt crises up to national bankruptcy .

Within the Eurosystem , monetary policy that uses the means of purchasing government and corporate bonds ( Eurosystem securities purchase programs ) leads to increased TARGET2 balances, which would have to be settled in the event of a country leaving the Eurosystem. Insofar, default risks arise that can also have an indirect impact on the budgets of other member states.

Economic Theories

The policy of low interest rates usually leads to an increase in lending and thus the money supply ( money supply growth ). It is therefore seen as an expansionary monetary policy . According to quantity theory , the expansion of the money supply leads to an inflation in the prices of goods and services. However, if the traditional credit creation process is disrupted, it can result in essentially just asset price inflation.

According to John Maynard Keynes , an expansionary monetary policy loses its investment-stimulating and stimulating effect if individuals prefer to keep the money in their coffers. According to his liquidity preference theory, such a situation occurs when individuals do not consider investing their money to be worthwhile due to low market interest rates and returns and they prefer to wait for better investment opportunities in the future ( liquidity trap ).

According to the monetary overinvestment theory, lowering the interest rate through monetary policy measures leads to artificial boom phases, which in turn lead to sharp economic downturns.

Supporters of the piggy bank theory such as Carl Christian von Weizsäcker , Ben Bernanke and Philip R. Lane assume, in accordance with the loanable funds theory , that the main cause of low interest rates is the savings glut , i.e. an oversupply of saved capital. Critics of this real economic approach point in particular to the empirical finding, incompatible with the piggy bank theory, of the decline in gross and net savings rates since the 1980s with a simultaneous decline in real interest rates.

Economist Ulrich van Suntum considers the creation of money (“money glut”) practiced in a low interest rate environment to be a system in which low interest rates and ultimately unsustainable national debt build up each other until the entire system collapses. The higher the national debt, the more difficult it becomes to return to "normal" market rates. Other experts, including those responsible at the Bank for International Settlements , fear that persistently low key interest rates would make it more difficult to reverse the expansionary monetary policy or that the low interest rate policy will become more and more a one-way street.

Reception of the low interest rate policy in the euro zone

Legal opinion

In a legal opinion, which was presented in Berlin on October 1, 2019, the Hamburg legal scholar Kai-Oliver Knops comes to the opinion that the negative interest rates charged by the European Central Bank since June 11, 2014 are unlawful. Under European law, the European Central Bank is neither formally nor materially authorized to collect them. Sufficient justification and parliamentary participation are lacking for such far-reaching measures. Knops assesses the negative interest as charges that violate the subsidiarity principle (Art. 5 Para. 3 TEU) and, in accordance with the case law of the European Court of Justice, also do not respect the proportionality principle (Art. 5 para. 4 TEU).

survey

According to a survey published in 2020 by an opinion research institute, 61 percent of the German citizens questioned declared the low interest rate policy to be wrong, after 53 percent rejection in the previous year, a maximum since the survey began in 2016. 29 percent, however, supported the low interest rate policy.

See also

literature

  • Horst Fugger: Stock Exchange Lexicon. Börsenwissen from A to Z . Finanzbuch Verlag, Munich 2007, ISBN 978-3-89879-191-5 , p. 130.

Web links

Wiktionary: low interest rate policy  - explanations of meanings, word origins, synonyms, translations

Individual evidence

  1. ↑ The key interest rate development of the Japanese central bank from 1975 to 2020 (as of March 11, 2020) , website in the de.statista.com portal , accessed on August 13, 2020
  2. ^ Nouriel Roubini : The New Abnormal for a Troubled Global Economy . Article from January 14, 2016 in the time.com portal , accessed on August 13, 2020
  3. Marco Bargel: Risks of the low interest rate policy for financial stability in the euro area . In: Quarterly issues for economic research . Duncker & Humblot, Berlin 2016, Volume 85, Issue 1, pp. 81–94 ( PDF )
  4. Tim Kanning: The fear of bankruptcies is growing . Article from August 31, 2020 in the faz.net portal , accessed on August 31, 2020
  5. Gerhard Rösl, Karl-Heinz Tödter: How expensive is the ECB's low interest rate policy for Germany? In: ifo Schnelldienst , 7/2015, volume 68, April 9, 2015, p. 44 ( PDF )
  6. Christian Knapp: On the concept of the liquidity trap: Critical analysis based on alternative specifications of the Phillips curve . (= Dissertation Helmut Schmidt University, Hamburg 2015), Springer Gabler, Springer Fachmedien, Wiesbaden 2016, ISBN 978-3-658-12339-0 , p. 1 ff.
  7. Gerhard Massenbauer: Never again interest: How you can still make money in the zero interest ice age . Finanzbuch Verlag, Munich 2017, ISBN 978-3-95972-054-0 , chapter 1.3
  8. Peter Bofinger , Mathias Ries: Flood of savings and low interest rates: In the economy, too, the earth revolves around the sun . Der Markoökonom, August 1, 2017, accessed on December 16, 2019
  9. Ulrich van Suntum : Money glut or money glut? . Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, December 15, 2019, accessed on December 15, 2019
  10. ^ Bank for International Settlements : 80th Annual Report of the BIS . Basel, June 2010, p. 43 ( PDF )
  11. Marco Bargel, p. 92
  12. Frank Matthias Drost: Expert opinion assesses negative ECB interest rates as unlawful . Article from October 1, 2019 in the portal handelsblatt .com , accessed on October 1, 2019
  13. Press release from the lawyers Schirp & Partner ECB minus interest rates are illegal. Bank repayment claims amounting to 40 billion euros. Bank customers can also defend themselves against charges. , Website from October 1, 2019 in the dgap.de portal , accessed on October 1, 2019
  14. More and more Germans reject the ECB's low interest rate policy . Article from February 12, 2020 in the handelsblatt.com portal , accessed on August 9, 2020