John T. McCutcheon and Great Depression: Difference between pages

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Difference between pages)
Content deleted Content added
add image
 
 
Line 1: Line 1:
{{redirect|The Great Depression}}
[[Image:McCutcheonNY1905.jpg|thumb|250px|[[Baby New Year]] 1905 chases old 1904 into the history books in this cartoon by [[John T. McCutcheon]]]]
[[Image:Lange-MigrantMother02.jpg|thumb|[[Dorothea Lange]]'s ''[[Migrant Mother]]'' depicts destitute [[Pea-pickers|pea pickers]] in [[California]], centering on [[Florence Owens Thompson]], a mother of seven children, age 32, in [[Nipomo, California]], March 1936.]]
'''John Tinney McCutcheon''' ([[May 6]] [[1870]] – [[June 10]] [[1949]]) was an American newspaper political cartoonist.


The '''Great Depression''' was a worldwide economic [[Recession|downturn]] starting in most places in 1929 and ending at different times in the 1930s or early 1940s for different countries. It was the largest and most important economic depression in modern history, and is used in the 21st century as a benchmark on how far the world's economy can fall. The Great Depression originated in the United States; historians most often use as a starting date the [[stock market crash]] on October 29, 1929, known as [[Wall Street Crash of 1929|Black Tuesday]]. The end of the depression in the U.S. is associated with the onset of the [[war economy]] of [[World War II]], beginning around 1939.<ref>{{cite book |title=The Cambridge Economic History of the United States |last=L. Engerman |first=Stanley |authorlink=Stanley L. Engerman |coauthors= Gallman, Robert E. }} </ref>
McCutcheon was born near [[South Raub, Indiana|South Raub]], [[Tippecanoe County, Indiana]] to Captain John Barr McCutcheon and Clara Glick McCutcheon. He graduated from [[Purdue University]], where he became a member of the [[Sigma Chi]] fraternity, in 1889 with a Bachelor of Science degree. At Purdue, he worked with typographer [[Bruce Rogers]] on the student newspaper and yearbook. There is now a [[dormitory]] at Purdue university and [[McCutcheon High School]], in [[Tippecanoe County, Indiana]], named in his honor.


The depression had devastating effects both in the [[developed country|developed]] and [[developing country|developing]] world. International trade was deeply affected, as were personal [[income]]s, [[tax revenue]]s, [[price]]s, and [[profit]]s. [[Cities in the Great Depression|Cities all around the world]] were hit hard, especially those dependent on [[heavy industry]]. Construction was virtually halted in many countries. [[Farming]] and rural areas suffered as crop prices fell by 40 to 60 percent.<ref>{{cite journal|author= Cochrane, Willard W.|title=Farm Prices, Myth and Reality|year=1958|pages=15}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|journal=[[League of Nations]]|title=World Economic Survey 1932–33|pages=43}}</ref> Facing plummeting demand with few alternate sources of jobs, areas dependent on [[Primary sector of economic activity|primary sector industries]] such as farming, [[mining]] and [[logging]] suffered the most.<ref>{{cite book
He worked at the '''Chicago Morning News''' (later called the '''Chicago Record''') and then at the [[Chicago Tribune]] from 1903 until his retirement in 1946.
| last = Hakim
| first = Joy
| title = A History of Us: War, Peace and all that Jazz
| publisher = [[Oxford University Press]]
| year = 1995
| location = [[New York]]
| isbn = 0-19509484-0}}.</ref>
Even shortly after the Wall Street Crash of 1929, optimism persisted. [[John D. Rockefeller]] said that "These are days when many are discouraged. In the 93 years of my life, depressions have come and gone. Prosperity has always returned and will again."<ref>{{cite web
|url= http://us.history.wisc.edu/hist102/lectures/lecture18.html
|title= Crashing Hopes: The Great Depression
|accessdate= 2008-03-13
|last= Schultz
|first= Stanley K.
|year= 1999
|work= American History 102: Civil War to the Present
|publisher= [[University of Wisconsin-Madison]]
}}.</ref>


The Great Depression ended at different times in different countries; for subsequent history see [[Home front during World War II]]. The majority of countries set up relief programs, and most underwent some sort of political upheaval, pushing them to the left or right. In some states, the desperate citizens turned toward nationalist [[Demagogy|demagogues]] - the most infamous being [[Adolf Hitler]] - setting the stage for [[World War II]] in 1939.
He was awarded the [[Pulitzer Prize]] for Cartoons in 1932.
Often called the "Dean of American Cartoonists", McCutcheon died [[June 10]] [[1949]] in [[Lake Forest, Illinois]].


==The snowball spiral==
He was the younger brother of novelist [[George Barr McCutcheon]], writer of the "Graustark" books.
The Great Depression was not a sudden total collapse. The stock market turned upward in early 1930, returning to early 1929 levels by April, though still almost 30 percent below the peak of September 1929.<ref>{{cite web|accessdate=2008-05-22|url=http://www.gold-eagle.com/editorials_98/vronsky060698.html|title=1998/99 Prognosis Based Upon 1929 Market Autopsy|publisher=Gold Eagle}}.</ref> Together, government and business actually spent more in the first half of 1930 than in the corresponding period of the previous year. But consumers, many of whom had suffered severe losses in the stock market the previous year, cut back their expenditures by ten percent, and a severe drought ravaged the agricultural heartland of the USA beginning in the northern summer of 1930.


In early 1930, credit was ample and available at low rates, but people were reluctant to add new debt by borrowing.{{fact | date=October 2008}} By May 1930, auto sales had declined to below the levels of 1928. Prices in general began to decline, but wages held steady in 1930, then began to drop in 1931. Conditions were worst in farming areas, where commodity prices plunged, and in mining and logging areas, where unemployment was high and there were few other jobs. The decline in the [[Economy of the United States|American economy]] was the factor that pulled down most other countries at first, then internal weaknesses or strengths in each country made conditions worse or better. Frantic attempts to shore up the economies of individual nations through [[protectionism|protectionist]] policies, such as the 1930 U.S. [[Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act]] and retaliatory tariffs in other countries, exacerbated the collapse in global trade. By late in 1930, a steady decline set in which reached bottom by March 1933.
On the Purdue Campus, McCutcheon is memorialized in a coeducational dormitory, [[John T. McCutcheon Hall]]. The lobby displays an original of one of his drawings, a nearly life-size drawing of a young man.


==Works==
==Causes ==
There were multiple causes for the first downturn in 1929, including the structural weaknesses and specific events that turned it into a major depression and the way in which the downturn spread from country to country. In relation to the 1929 downturn, historians emphasize structural factors like massive bank failures and the stock market crash, while economists (such as Peter Temin and Barry Eichengreen) point to Britain's decision to return to the Gold Standard at pre-World War I parities (US$4.86:£1).
* ''Cartoons: A Selection of One Hundred Drawings'' (1903) - with introduction by [[George Ade]]

* ''Bird Center Cartoons; A chronicle of social happenings at Bird Center Illinois'' 1904
{{Main|Causes of the Great Depression}}
* ''The Mysterious Stranger and Other Cartoons'' (1905)

* ''[http://www.tkinter.smig.net/Chicago/InjunSummer/ Injun Summer]'' (1907)
Recession cycles are thought to be a normal part of living in a world of inexact balances between [[supply and demand]]. What turns a usually mild and short recession or "ordinary" [[business cycle]] into a great depression is a subject of debate and concern. Scholars have not agreed on the exact causes and their relative importance. The search for causes is closely connected to the question of how to avoid a future depression, and so the political and policy viewpoints of scholars are mixed into the analysis of historic events eight decades ago. The even larger question is whether it was largely a failure on the part of [[free market]]s or largely a failure on the part of governments to curtail widespread bank failures, the resulting panics, and reduction in the money supply. Those who believe in a large role for governments in the economy believe it was mostly a failure of the free markets and those who believe in free markets believe it was mostly a failure of government that compounded the problem.
* ''T.R. in Cartoons'' (1910)

* ''Drawn from Memory - The Autobiography of John T. McCutcheon'', The Bobbs-Merrill Company (1950)
Current theories may be broadly classified into three main points of view. First, there is orthodox [[classical economics]]: [[Monetarism|monetarist]], [[Austrian Economics]] and [[neoclassical economics|neoclassical economic theory]], all of which focus on the [[macroeconomic]] effects of [[money supply]] and the supply of gold which backed many currencies before the Great Depression, including [[Mass production|production]] and [[Consumption (economics)|consumption]].
[[Image:Gdp20-40.jpg|thumb|Chart 1: USA GDP annual pattern and long-term trend, 1920-40, in billions of constant dollars<ref>{{cite book|author=Carter, Susan|title=Historical Statistics of the US: Millennial Edition|year=2006}}</ref>.]]

Second, there are structural theories, most importantly [[Keynesian economics|Keynesian]], but also including those of [[institutional economics]], that point to [[underconsumption]] and overinvestment ([[economic bubble]]), [[malfeasance]] by bankers and industrialists, or incompetence by government officials. The only consensus viewpoint is that there was a large-scale lack of confidence. Unfortunately, once panic and deflation set in, many people believed they could make more money by keeping clear of the markets as prices got lower and lower and a given amount of money bought ever more goods.

Third, there is the [[Marxist]] critique of political economy. This emphasizes contradictions within capital itself (which is viewed as a social relation involving the appropriation of surplus value) as giving rise to an inherently unbalanced dynamic of accumulation resulting in an overaccumulation of capital, culminating in periodic crises of devaluation of capital. The origin of crisis is thus located firmly in the sphere of production, though economic crisis can be aggravated by problems of disproportionality of over-production in the manufacturing and related production sectors and the underconsumption of the masses.

[[Image:1930Industry.svg|thumb|US industrial production (1928-39).]]

===Debt===
[[Image:American union bank.gif|thumb|right|Crowd at New York's American Union Bank during a [[bank run]] early in the Great Depression. ]]
[[Debt]] is seen as one of the causes of the Great Depression<ref>http://encarta.msn.com/encyclopedia_761584403/Great_Depression_in_the_United_States.html#s11</ref>, particularly in the [[United States]]{{Fact|date=September 2008}}. [[Macroeconomist]]s including [[Ben Bernanke]], the current chairman of the [[U.S. Federal Reserve Bank]], have revived the debt-deflation view{{Fact|date=September 2008}} of the Great Depression originated by [[Arthur Cecil Pigou]] and [[Irving Fisher]]:{{Fact|date=September 2008}} in the 1920s, American consumers and businesses relied on cheap credit{{Fact|date=September 2008}}, the former to purchase consumer goods such as automobiles and furniture, and the latter for capital investment to increase production{{Fact|date=September 2008}}. This fueled strong short-term growth but created consumer and commercial debt{{Fact|date=September 2008}}. People and businesses who were deeply in debt when [[Deflation (economics)|price deflation]] occurred or demand for their product decreased often risked default{{Fact|date=September 2008}}. Many drastically cut current spending to keep up time payments, thus lowering demand for new products. Businesses began to fail as [[Construction|construction work]] and factory orders plunged.

Massive layoffs occurred, resulting in US unemployment rates of over 25% by 1933. Banks which had financed this debt began to fail as debtors defaulted on debt and depositors attempted to withdraw their deposits en masse, triggering multiple [[bank run]]s. Government guarantees and Federal Reserve banking regulations to prevent such panics were ineffective or not used. Bank failures led to the loss of billions of dollars in assets.<ref name = "lhf-30s">{{cite web|accessdate=2008-05-22|url=http://www.livinghistoryfarm.org/farminginthe30s/money_08.html|title=Bank Failures |publisher=Living History Farm}}</ref> Outstanding debts became heavier, because prices and incomes fell by 20–50% but the debts remained at the same dollar amount. After the panic of 1929, and during the first 10 months of 1930, 744 US banks failed. (In all, 9,000 banks failed during the 1930s). By 1933, depositors had lost $140 billion in deposits.<ref name = "lhf-30s">{{cite web|accessdate=2008-05-22|url=http://www.livinghistoryfarm.org/farminginthe30s/money_08.html|title=Bank Failures |publisher=Living History Farm}}</ref>

Bank failures snowballed as desperate bankers called in loans which the borrowers did not have time or money to repay. With future profits looking poor, [[Investment|capital investment]] and construction slowed or completely ceased. In the face of bad loans and worsening future prospects, the surviving banks became even more conservative in their lending.<ref name = "lhf-30s"/> Banks built up their capital reserves and made fewer loans, which intensified deflationary pressures. A [[Virtuous circle and vicious circle|vicious cycle]] developed and the downward spiral accelerated. This kind of self-aggravating process may have turned a 1930 recession into a 1933 great depression.

===Trade decline and the U.S. Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act===
{{main|Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act}}
Many economists have argued that the sharp decline in international trade after 1930 helped to worsen the depression, especially for countries significantly dependent on foreign trade. Most historians and economists partly blame the American [[Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act]] (enacted June 17, 1930) for worsening the depression by seriously reducing international trade and causing retaliatory tariffs in other countries. Foreign trade was a small part of overall economic activity in the United States and was concentrated in a few businesses like farming; it was a much larger factor in many other countries.<ref>{{cite web|accessdate=2008-05-22|url=http://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/intrel/depress.htm|title=The World in Depression|publisher=[[Mount Holyoke College]]}}</ref> The average ''[[ad valorem]]'' rate of duties on dutiable imports for 1921–1925 was 25.9% but under the new tariff it jumped to 50% in 1931–1935.

In dollar terms, American exports declined from about $5.2 billion in 1929 to $1.7 billion in 1933; but prices also fell, so the physical volume of exports only fell by half. Hardest hit were farm commodities such as wheat, cotton, tobacco, and lumber. According to this theory, the collapse of farm exports caused many American farmers to default on their loans, leading to the [[bank run]]s on small rural banks that characterized the early years of the Great Depression.

===U.S. Federal Reserve and money supply===
[[Monetarist]]s, including [[Milton Friedman]] and current [[Federal Reserve System]] chairman [[Ben Bernanke]], argue that the Great Depression was caused by [[Contractionary monetary policy|monetary contraction]], the consequence of poor policymaking by the American [[Federal Reserve System]] and continuous crisis in the banking system.<ref>{{cite book|author= [[Ben Bernanke|Bernanke, Ben S.]]|year=2000|title=Essays on the Great Depression|publisher=[[Princeton University Press]]|page=7|isbn=0691016984}}</ref><ref>
{{cite web
|url=http://www.worldnetdaily.com/index.php?fa=PAGE.view&pageId=59405
|title=Bernanke: Federal Reserve caused Great Depression
|publisher=[[WorldNetDaily]]
|accessdate=2008-03-21
}}
</ref> In this view, the Federal Reserve, by not acting, allowed the money supply as measured by the [[M2 (economics)|M2]] to shrink by one-third from 1929 to 1933. Friedman argued<ref>{{cite book|title=A Monetary History of the United States}}</ref> that the downward turn in the economy, starting with the stock market crash, would have been just another recession. The problem was that some large, public bank failures, particularly that of the [[New York Bank of the United States|Bank of the United States]], produced panic and widespread runs on local banks, and that the Federal Reserve sat idly by while banks fell. He claimed that, if the Fed had provided emergency lending to these key banks, or simply bought [[government bond]]s on the [[open market]] to provide liquidity and increase the quantity of money after the key banks fell, all the rest of the banks would not have fallen after the large ones did, and the money supply would not have fallen as far and as fast as it did.<ref>{{cite web|accessdate=2008-05-22|url=http://www.nybooks.com/articles/19857|title=Who Was Milton Friedman?|work=[[The New York Review of Books]]|date=2007-02-15|author=Krugman, Paul}}</ref> With significantly less money to go around, businessmen could not get new loans and could not even get their old loans renewed, forcing many to stop investing. This interpretation blames the Federal Reserve for inaction, especially the New York branch.<ref>{{cite book
| last = Griffin
| first = G. Edward
| title = The Creature from Jekyll Island: A Second Look at the Federal Reserve
| publisher = [[American Media (publisher)]]
| year = 2002
| isbn = 0912986395
| isbn-13 = 978-0912986395 }}</ref>

One reason why the Federal Reserve did not act to limit the decline of the money supply was regulation. At that time the amount of credit the Federal Reserve could issue was limited by laws which required partial gold backing of that credit. By the late 1920s the Federal Reserve had almost hit the limit of allowable credit that could be backed by the gold in its possession. This credit was in the form of Federal Reserve demand notes. Since a "promise of gold" is not as good as "gold in the hand", during the bank panics a portion of those demand notes were redeemed for Federal Reserve gold. Since the Federal Reserve had hit its limit on allowable credit, any reduction in gold in its vaults had to be accompanied by a greater reduction in credit. Several years into the Great Depression, the private ownership of gold was declared illegal, reducing the pressure on Federal Reserve gold.

===Austrian School explanations===
Another explanation comes from the [[Austrian School]] of economics. Theorists of the "Austrian School" who wrote about the Depression include Austrian economist [[Friedrich Hayek]] and American economist [[Murray Rothbard]], who wrote ''[[America's Great Depression]]'' (1963). In their view, the key cause of the Depression was the expansion of the money supply in the 1920s that led to an unsustainable credit-driven boom. In their view, the Federal Reserve, which was created in 1913, shoulders much of the blame.

In opinion, Hayek, writing for the Austrian Institute of Economic Research Report in February 1929<ref>{{cite journal|title=Austrian Institute of Economic Research Report|month=February | year=1929}}</ref> predicted the economic downturn, stating that "the boom will collapse within the next few months."

Ludwig von Mises also expected this financial catastrophe, and is quoted as stating "A great crash is coming, and I don't want my name in any way connected with it,"<ref>{{cite book|author= Mises, Margit von|title=My Years with Ludwig von Mises|publisher=Arlington House|year=1976|page=31}}</ref> when he turned down an important job at the Kreditanstalt Bank in early 1929.

One reason for the monetary inflation was to help [[Great Britain]], which, in the 1920s, was struggling with its plans to return to the gold standard at pre-war ([[World War I]]) parity. Returning to the gold standard at this rate meant that the British economy was facing deflationary pressure.<ref name="rothbard 2002 141">{{harvnb|Rothbard|2002|p=141}}</ref> According to Rothbard, the lack of price flexibility in Britain meant that unemployment shot up, and the American government was asked to help. The United States was receiving a net inflow of gold, and inflated further in order to help Britain return to the gold standard. [[Montagu Norman]], head of the Bank of England, had an especially good relationship with [[Benjamin Strong Jr.|Benjamin Strong]], the ''de facto'' head of the Federal Reserve. Norman pressured the heads of the central banks of France and Germany to inflate as well, but unlike Strong, they refused.<ref name="rothbard 2002 141" /> Rothbard says American inflation was meant to allow Britain to inflate as well, because under the gold standard, Britain could not inflate on its own.

In the Austrian view it was this inflation of the money supply that led to an unsustainable boom in both asset prices (stocks and bonds) and capital goods. By the time the Fed belatedly tightened in 1928, it was far too late and, in the Austrian view, a depression was inevitable.

The artificial interference in the economy was a disaster prior to the Depression, and government efforts to prop up the economy after the crash of 1929 only made things worse. According to Rothbard, government intervention delayed the market's adjustment and made the road to complete recovery more difficult.<ref>{{harvnb|Rothbard|2002|p=25}}</ref>

Furthermore, Rothbard criticizes Milton Friedman's assertion that the central bank failed to inflate the supply of money. Rothbard asserts that the Federal Reserve bought $1.1 billion of government securities from February to July 1932, raising its total holding to $1.8 billion. Total bank reserves rose by only $212 million, but Rothbard argues that this was because the American populace lost faith in the banking system and began hoarding more cash, a factor quite beyond the control of the Central Bank. The potential for a run on the banks caused local bankers to be more conservative in lending out their reserves, and this, Rothbard argues, was the cause of the Federal Reserve's inability to inflate.<ref>{{harvnb|Rothbard|2002|pp=293–294}}</ref>

[[Image:Tenantless farm Texas panhandle 1938.jpg|thumb|left|Power farming displaces tenants from the land in the western dry cotton area. Childress County, Texas, 1938.]]

===Business===
[[Franklin D. Roosevelt]], elected in 1932, primarily blamed the excesses of big business for causing an unstable bubble-like economy. Democrats believed the problem was that business had too much money, and the [[New Deal]] was intended as a remedy, by empowering [[Trade union|labor unions]] and farmers and by raising taxes on corporate profits. Regulation of the economy was a favorite remedy. Some New Deal regulation (the NRA and AAA) was declared unconstitutional by the [[Supreme Court of the United States|U.S. Supreme Court]]. Most New Deal regulations were abolished or scaled back in the 1970s and 1980s in a bipartisan wave of [[deregulation]].<ref>{{cite book|author= Vietor, Richard H. K.|title=Contrived Competition: Regulation and Deregulation in America|year=1994}}</ref> However the [[Securities and Exchange Commission]], [[Federal Reserve]], and [[Social Security (United States)|Social Security]] won widespread support.

===Lack of government deficit spending===
British economist [[John Maynard Keynes]] argued in ''[[General Theory of Employment Interest and Money]]'' that lower aggregate expenditures in the economy contributed to a massive decline in income and to employment that was well below the average. In this situation, the economy might have reached a perfect balance, at a cost of high unemployment. Keynesian economists called on governments during times of [[Crisis (economic)|economic crisis]] to pick up the slack by increasing [[government spending]] and/or cutting taxes.

Massive increases in [[deficit spending]], new [[Bank regulation|banking regulation]], and boosting farm prices did start turning the U.S. economy around in 1933,{{Fact|date=January 2008}} but it was a slow and painful process. The U.S. had not returned to 1929's GNP for over a decade and still had an unemployment rate of about 15% in 1940 — down from 25% in 1933.

===Inequality of wealth and income===
[[Marriner S. Eccles]], who served as [[Franklin D. Roosevelt]]'s [[Chairman of the Federal Reserve]] from November 1934 to February 1948, detailed what he believed caused the Depression in his memoirs, ''Beckoning Frontiers'' (New York, Alfred A. Knopf, 1951)<ref name=Beckoning>{{cite book | last = Eccles | first = Marriner S. | authorlink = Marriner S. Eccles | title = Beckoning Frontiers: Public and Personal Recollections | publisher = Alfred A. Knopf |edition = 1st | year = 1951 | location = New York | pages = 499 | oclc = 3720103}}</ref>:
<blockquote>
''As mass production has to be accompanied by mass consumption, mass consumption, in turn, implies a distribution of wealth -- not of existing wealth, but of wealth as it is currently produced -- to provide men with buying power equal to the amount of goods and services offered by the nation's economic machinery.'' [Emphasis in original.]
<p>
Instead of achieving that kind of distribution, a giant suction pump had by 1929-30 drawn into a few hands an increasing portion of currently produced wealth. This served them as capital accumulations. But by taking purchasing power out of the hands of mass consumers, the savers denied to themselves the kind of effective demand for their products that would justify a reinvestment of their capital accumulations in new plants. In consequence, as in a poker game where the chips were concentrated in fewer and fewer hands, the other fellows could stay in the game only by borrowing. When their credit ran out, the game stopped.
<p>
That is what happened to us in the twenties. We sustained high levels of employment in that period with the aid of an exceptional expansion of debt outside of the banking system. This debt was provided by the large growth of business savings as well as savings by individuals, particularly in the upper-income groups where taxes were relatively low. Private debt outside of the banking system increased about fifty per cent. This debt, which was at high interest rates, largely took the form of mortgage debt on housing, office, and hotel structures, consumer installment debt, brokers' loans, and foreign debt. The stimulation to spend by debt-creation of this sort was short-lived and could not be counted on to sustain high levels of employment for long periods of time. Had there been a better distribution of the current income from the national product -- in other words, had there been less savings by business and the higher-income groups and more income in the lower groups -- we should have had far greater stability in our economy. Had the six billion dollars, for instance, that were loaned by corporations and wealthy individuals for stock-market speculation been distributed to the public as lower prices or higher wages and with less profits to the corporations and the well-to-do, it would have prevented or greatly moderated the economic collapse that began at the end of 1929.
<p>
The time came when there were no more poker chips to be loaned on credit. Debtors thereupon were forced to curtail their consumption in an effort to create a margin that could be applied to the reduction of outstanding debts. This naturally reduced the demand for goods of all kinds and brought on what seemed to be overproduction, but was in reality underconsumption when judged in terms of the real world instead of the money world. This, in turn, brought about a fall in prices and employment.
<p>
Unemployment further decreased the consumption of goods, which further increased unemployment, thus closing the circle in a continuing decline of prices. Earnings began to disappear, requiring economies of all kinds in the wages, salaries, and time of those employed. And thus again the vicious circle of deflation was closed until one third of the entire working population was unemployed, with our national income reduced by fifty per cent, and with the aggregate debt burden greater than ever before, not in dollars, but measured by current values and income that represented the ability to pay. Fixed charges, such as taxes, railroad and other utility rates, insurance and interest charges, clung close to the 1929 level and required such a portion of the national income to meet them that the amount left for consumption of goods was not sufficient to support the population.
<p>
This then, was my reading of what brought on the depression.
<p>
</blockquote>

==Literature==
The U.S. Depression has been the subject of much writing, as the country has sought to re-evaluate an era that caused emotional as well as financial trauma to its people. Perhaps the most noteworthy and famous novel written on the subject is ''[[The Grapes of Wrath]]'', published in 1939 and written by [[John Steinbeck]], who was awarded both the [[Nobel Prize]] for literature and the [[Pulitzer Prize]] for the work. The novel focuses on a poor family of sharecroppers who are forced from their home as drought, economic hardship, and changes in the [[Agriculture|agricultural industry]] occur during the Great Depression. Steinbeck's ''[[Of Mice and Men]]'' is another important novel about a journey during the Great Depression. ''The Great Depression'' is a novella written by Alon Bersharder about a sad, disgruntled temporary worker, making the title both a homage to the historical event and a pun. Additionally, Harper Lee's ''[[To Kill a Mockingbird]]'' is set during the Great Depression. Margaret Atwood's Booker prize-winning ''[[The Blind Assassin]]'' is likewise set in the Great Depression, centering on a privileged socialite's love affair with a Marxist revolutionary.

==Effects==
===Australia===
{{main|Great Depression in Australia}}
Australia's extreme dependence on agricultural and industrial [[export]]s meant it was one of the hardest-hit countries in the [[Western world]], amongst the likes of Canada and Germany. Falling export demand and commodity prices placed massive downward pressures on wages. Further, [[unemployment]] reached a record high of almost 32% in 1932, with incidents of [[civil unrest]] becoming common. After 1932, an increase in wool and meat prices led to a gradual recovery.

===Canada===
[[Image:UnemployedMarch.jpg|thumb|right|200px|Unemployed men march in Toronto, Ontario, Canada.]]
{{main|Great Depression in Canada}}
Harshly impacted by both the global economic downturn and the [[Dust Bowl]], Canadian industrial production had fallen to only 58% of the 1929 level by 1932, the second lowest level in the world after the United States, and well behind nations such as Britain, which saw it fall only to 83% of the 1929 level. Total national income fell to 55% of the 1929 level, again worse than any nation apart from the United States.

===France===
{{main|Great Depression in France}}
The Depression began to affect France from about 1931. France's relatively high degree of self-sufficiency meant the damage was considerably less than in nations like Germany. However, hardship and unemployment were high enough to lead to rioting and the rise of the [[socialist]] [[Popular Front (France)|Popular Front]].

===Germany===
{{main|Great Depression in Central Europe}}
Germany's [[Weimar Republic]] was hit hard by the depression, as American loans to help rebuild the German economy now stopped. Unemployment soared, especially in larger cities, and the [[political system]] veered toward [[extremism]]. Repayment of the war reparations due by Germany were suspended in 1932 following the [[Lausanne Conference of 1932]]. By that time Germany had repaid 1/8th of the reparations. [[Adolf Hitler|Hitler]]'s [[National Socialist German Workers Party|Nazi Party]] came to power in January 1933.

===Japan===
The Great Depression did not strongly affect [[Japan]]. The Japanese economy shrank by 8% during 1929&ndash;31. However, Japan was fortunate to have far sighted Minister of Finance (MoF) [[Osachi Hamaguchi]] at the time who implemented the first version of [[Keynesian economics|Keynesian economic]] policies: first, by increasing [[deficit spending]]; and second, by devaluing [[Yen|the currency]]. The MoF believed that the deficit spending could easily be paid for when productivity improved.

The devaluation of the currency had an immediate effect. Quickly, Japanese textiles began to displace British textiles in export markets. The deficit spending, however proved to be most profound. The deficit spending went into the purchase of munitions for the armed forces. By 1933, Japan was already out of the depression. By 1934 the MoF realized that the economy was in danger of overheating, and to avoid inflation, moved to reduce the deficit spending that went towards armaments and munitions. This resulted in a strong and swift negative reaction from nationalists, especially those in the Army, culminating in the assassination of the MoF. This had a [[chilling effect (term)|chilling effect]] on all civilian bureaucrats in the Japanese government. From 1934, the military's dominance of the government continued to grow. Instead of reducing deficit spending, the government introduced price controls and rationing schemes that reduced, but did not eliminate inflation, which would remain a problem until the end of [[World War II]].

The deficit spending had a transformative effect on Japan. Japan's industrial production doubled during the 1930s. Further, in 1929 the list of the largest firms in Japan was dominated by light industries, especially textile companies (many of Japan's automakers, like [[Toyota]], have their roots in the textile industry). By 1940 light industry had been displaced by heavy industry as the largest firms inside the Japanese economy. (For more on the Japanese economy in the 1930s see "MITI and the Japanese Miracle" by Chalmers Johnson).

These events obviously set the stage for World War II. In 1929, Japan's GNP was about a sixth of the U.S. and its per capita GNP was about a third. However, during the 1930s, the U.S. economy contracted by a third. By 1939, Japan's GNP was nearly half that of the United States, and its per capita GNP was nearly equal to the United States. Face with having to face two Oceans, it was easy to see how some Japanese planners felt that they had an even chance against the U.S. What they may not have considered is that the U.S. had yet to truly kick in deficit financing for munitions until after 1940 - where upon the United States would experience its own doubling of industrial production in four short years.

===Latin America===
{{Main|Great Depression in Latin America}}
Because of high levels of United States investment in Latin American economies, they were severely damaged by the Depression. Within the region, [[Chile]], [[Bolivia]] and [[Peru]] were particularly badly affected. One result of the Depression in this area was the rise of [[fascist]] movements.
{{Fact|date=October 2008}}

===Netherlands===
{{main|Great Depression in the Netherlands}}
From roughly 1931 until 1937, the Netherlands suffered a deep and exceptionally long depression. This depression was partly caused by the after-effects of the [[Wall Street Crash of 1929|Stock Market Crash of 1929]] in the United States, and partly by internal factors in the Netherlands. Government policy, especially the very late dropping of the [[Gold Standard]], played a role in prolonging the depression. The Great Depression in the Netherlands led to some political instability and riots, and can be linked to the rise of the Dutch national-socialist party [[Nationaal Socialistische Beweging|NSB]]. The depression in the Netherlands eased off somewhat at the end of 1936, when the government finally dropped the [[Gold Standard]], but real economic stability did not return until after [[World War II]].

===South Africa===
{{main|Great Depression in South Africa}}
As world trade slumped, demand for South African agricultural and mineral exports fell drastically. It is believed that the social discomfort caused by the depression was a contributing factor in the 1933 split between the "gesuiwerde" (purified) and "smelter" (fusionist) factions within the [[National Party (South Africa)|National Party]] and the National Party's subsequent fusion with the [[South African Party]].

===Soviet Union===
{{main|Economy of the Soviet Union#Economic development}}
Having removed itself from the capitalist [[world system]] both by choice and as a result of efforts of the capitalist powers to isolate it, the Great Depression had little effect on the Soviet Union. This was a period of industrial expansion for the USSR as it recovered from revolution and civil war, and its apparent immunity to the Great Depression seemed to validate the theory of Marxism and contributed to [[Socialist]] and [[Communist]] agitation in affected nations. This in turn increased fears of Communist revolution in the [[Western_world#Political|West]], strengthening support for [[anti-Communists]], both moderate and extreme.

===United Kingdom===
{{main|Great Depression in the United Kingdom}}

===United States===
{{main|Great Depression in the United States}}
====Early response====
[[Secretary of the Treasury]] [[Andrew W. Mellon|Andrew Mellon]] advised [[Herbert Hoover|President Hoover]] that [[Shock therapy (economics)|shock treatment]] would be the best response: "Liquidate labor, liquidate stocks, liquidate the farmers, liquidate [[real estate]].... That will purge the rottenness out of the system. High costs of living and high living will come down. People will work harder, live a more moral life. Values will be adjusted, and enterprising people will pick up the wrecks from less competent people."<ref>{{cite book|author=Hoover, Herbert|title=The memoirs of Herbert Hoover|chapter=3:9}}</ref> Hoover rejected this advice, and started numerous programs, all of which failed to reverse the downturn.<Ref> Waren, ''Herbert Hoover and the Great Depression''</ref>

Hoover launched a series of programs to increase farm prices, which failed, expanded federal spending in public works such as dams, and launched the [[Reconstruction Finance Corporation]] (RFC) which aided cities, banks and railroads, and continued as a major agency under the New Deal. To provide unemployment relief he set up the Emergency Relief Agency (ERA) that operated until 1935 as the Federal Emergency Relief Agency. Quarter by quarter the economy went downhill, as prices, profits and employment fell, leading to the political realignment in 1932 that brought to power the [[New Deal]].
[[Image:Gdp29-41.jpg|thumb|350px|GDP in constant (2000) dollars]]

====The New Deal====
{{Main|New Deal}}
Shortly after President Roosevelt was inaugurated in 1933, drought and erosion combined to cause the [[Dust Bowl]], shifting hundreds of thousands of [[displaced persons]] off their farms in the midwest. From his inauguration onward, Roosevelt argued that restructuring of the economy would be needed to prevent another depression or avoid prolonging the current one. New Deal programs sought to stimulate [[demand]] and provide work and relief for the impoverished through increased government spending and institute financial reforms. The [[Securities Act of 1933]] comprehensively regulated the securities industry. This was followed by the [[Securities Exchange Act of 1934]] which created the [[Securities and Exchange Commission]]. Though amended, key provisions of both Acts are still in force. Federal insurance of [[Deposit account|bank deposits]] was provided by the [[Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation|FDIC]], and the [[Glass-Steagall Act]]. The institution of the [[National Recovery Administration]] (NRA) remains a controversial act to this day. The NRA made a number of sweeping changes to the American economy until it [[Schechter v. United States|was deemed unconstitutional]] by the [[Supreme Court of the United States]] in 1935.

Early changes by the Roosevelt administration included:
* Instituting regulations to fight deflationary "cut-throat competition" through the NRA.
* Setting minimum prices and [[Minimum wage|wages]], labor standards, and competitive conditions in all industries through the NRA.
* Encouraging unions that would raise wages, to increase the [[purchasing power]] of the [[working class]].
* Cutting farm production to raise prices through the [[Agricultural Adjustment Act]] and its successors.
* Forcing businesses to work with government to set price codes through the NRA.

These reforms, together with several other relief and recovery measures are called the [[First New Deal]]. New regulations and attempts at economic stimulus through a new [[alphabet soup]] of agencies set up in 1933 and 1934 and previously extant agencies such as the [[Reconstruction Finance Corporation]] did not halt economic stagnation. By 1935, the "[[Second New Deal]]" added [[Social Security (United States)|Social Security]], a national [[Aid agency|relief agency]] (the [[Works Progress Administration]], WPA) and, through the [[National Labor Relations Board]], a strong stimulus to the growth of labor unions. Unemployment declined by over one-third in Roosevelt's first term (from 25% to 14.3%, 1933 to 1937), but faster than the economic upturn came 1938's "recession within a depression" and unemployment zoomed to 19%, then declined somewhat until the [[conscription|draft]] to fight [[World War II]] lowered it more. In 1929, federal expenditures constituted only 3% of the [[Gross domestic product|GDP]]. Expenditures as a proportion of GDP tripled{{Fact|date=September 2008}} between 1933 and 1939, accompanied by sizable deficits.{{Fact|date=September 2008}} The debt as a proportion of GNP rose under Hoover from 20% to 40%. Roosevelt kept it at 40% until the war began, when it soared to 128%. After the [[Recession of 1937]], conservatives were able to form a bipartisan [[conservative coalition]] to stop further expansion of the New Deal and, by 1943, had abolished all of the relief programs. In 1946, large-scale relaxation of government controls{{Fact|date=September 2008}} over the wartime economy, including a sharp reduction of taxes, allowed for increased innovation in consumer goods and a marked increase in consumer spending. Unemployment rates also returned to normal levels.{{Fact|date=September 2008}}

====Recession of 1937====
{{Main|Recession of 1937}}
In 1937 the American economy took an unexpected nosedive, lasting through most of 1938. Production declined sharply, as did profits and employment. Unemployment jumped from 14.3% in 1937 to 19.0% in 1938. The Roosevelt administration reacted by launching a rhetorical campaign against [[Monopoly|monopoly power]], which was cast as the cause of the depression, and by appointing [[Thurman Arnold]] to act; Arnold's effectiveness ended once [[World War II]] began and corporate energies had to be directed to winning the war.

The administration's other response to the 1937 deepening of the Great Depression had more tangible results. Ignoring the pleas of the [[United States Department of the Treasury|Treasury Department]], Roosevelt embarked on an antidote to the depression, reluctantly abandoning his efforts to balance the budget and launching a $5 billion spending program in the spring of 1938, an effort to increase mass purchasing power. Business-oriented observers explained the recession and recovery in very different terms from the Keynesians. They argued that the New Deal had been very hostile to business expansion in 1935–37, had encouraged massive strikes which had a negative impact on major industries such as automobiles, and had threatened massive antitrust legal attacks on big corporations. All those threats diminished sharply after 1938. For example, the antitrust efforts fizzled out without major cases. The CIO and AFL unions started battling each other more than with the corporations, and [[tax policy]] became more favorable to long-term growth, according to this argument.

On the other hand, according to economist [[Robert Higgs]], when looking only at the supply of consumer goods, significant [[Economic growth|GDP growth]] resumed only in 1946 (Higgs does not estimate the value to consumers of collective, intangible goods like victory in war). To Keynesians, the [[war economy]] showed just how large the fiscal stimulus required to end the downturn of the Depression was, and it led, at the time, to fears that as soon as America demobilized, it would return to Depression conditions, and industrial output would fall to pre-war levels. That incorrect Keynesian prediction that a new depression would start after the war failed to take into account massive savings and pent-up consumer demand, along with the ending of the restrictive wartime regulations in most consumer industries, and the cutting of high tax rates starting in 1946. In any case, government spending and changing regulations (first tightening them, then loosening them) appear to have contributed to the recovery, as consumer and producer behavior changed.

==Keynesian models==
In the early 1930s, before [[John Maynard Keynes]] wrote [[General Theory of Employment Interest and Money|''The General Theory'']], he was advocating [[public works]] programs and deficits as a way to get the British economy out of the Depression. Although Keynes never mentions fiscal policy in ''The General Theory'', and instead advocates the need to socialize investments, Keynes ushered in more of a theoretical revolution than a policy one. His basic idea was simple: to keep people fully employed, governments have to run deficits when the economy is slowing because the private sector will not invest enough to increase production and reverse the recession.

As the Depression wore on, Roosevelt tried public works, [[Agricultural subsidy|farm subsidies]], and other devices to restart the economy, but never completely gave up trying to balance the budget. According to the Keynesians, he needed to spend much more money; they were unable to say how much more. With [[fiscal policy]], however, government could provide the needed Keynesian spending by decreasing taxes, increasing government spending, and increasing individuals' incomes. As incomes increased, they would spend more. As they spent more, the [[multiplier effect]] would take over and expand the effect on the initial spending. The Keynesians did not estimate what the size of the multiplier was. Keynesian economists assumed poor people would spend new incomes; however, they saved much of the new money; that is, they paid back debts owed to landlords, grocers and family {{Fact|date=September 2008}}, which might have then spent the money. Keynesian ideas of the [[consumption function]] have been challenged, most notably in the 1950s by [[Milton Friedman]] and [[Franco Modigliani]].

== Neoclassical approach ==
Recent work from a neoclassical perspective focuses on the decline in productivity that caused the initial decline in output and a prolonged recovery due to policies that affected the labor market. This work, collected by Kehoe and Prescott,<ref>{{cite book|author=Kehoe, Timothy J.; Prescott, Edward C.|title=Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century|publisher=[[Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis]]|year=2007}}</ref> decomposes the economic decline into a decline in the labor force, capital stock, and the productivity with which these inputs are used. This study suggests that theories of the Great Depression have to explain an initial severe decline but rapid recovery in productivity, relatively little change in the capital stock, and a prolonged depression in the labor force. This analysis rejects theories that focus on the role of savings and posit a decline in the capital stock.

==Gold standard==
Every major currency left the [[gold standard]] during the Great Depression. [[Great Britain]] was the first to do so. Facing speculative attacks on the [[pound sterling|pound]] and depleting gold reserves, in September 1931 the [[Bank of England]] ceased exchanging pound notes for gold and the pound was floated on foreign exchange markets.

Great Britain, Japan, and the [[Scandinavia]]n countries left the gold standard in 1931. Other countries, such as Italy and the United States, remained on the gold standard into 1932 or 1933, while a few countries in the so-called "gold bloc", led by France and including [[Poland]], [[Belgium]] and [[Switzerland]], stayed on the standard until 1935-1936.

According to later analysis, the earliness with which a country left the gold standard reliably predicted its economic recovery. For example, Great Britain and Scandinavia, which left the gold standard in 1931, recovered much earlier than France and Belgium, which remained on gold much longer. Countries such as China, which had a [[silver standard]], almost avoided the depression entirely. The connection between leaving the gold standard as a strong predictor of that country's severity of its depression and the length of time of its recovery has been shown to be consistent for dozens of countries, including developing countries. This partly explains why the experience and length of the depression differed between national economies <ref>{{citation |last=Bernanke |first=Ben |date=March 2, 2004 |title=Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke: Money, Gold and the Great Depression |journal=At the H. Parker Willis Lecture in Economic Policy, Washington and Lee University, Lexington, Virginia |url=http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/200403022/default.htm}}</ref>.

==Rearmament and recovery==
The massive rearmament policies to counter the threat from [[Nazi Germany]] helped stimulate the economies of Europe in 1937-39. By 1937, unemployment in Britain had fallen to 1.5 million. The mobilization of manpower following the outbreak of war in 1939 finally ended unemployment.

In the United States, the massive war spending doubled the [[Gross national product|GNP]], either masking the effects of the Depression or essentially ending the Depression. Businessmen ignored the mounting [[national debt]] and heavy new taxes, redoubling their efforts for greater output to take advantage of [[Harry S. Truman#Truman committee|generous government contracts]]. Productivity soared: most people worked [[overtime]] and gave up leisure activities to make money after so many hard years. People accepted [[rationing]] and [[Incomes policy|price controls]] for the first time as a way of expressing their support for the [[war effort]]. [[Cost-plus pricing]] in munitions contracts guaranteed businesses a profit no matter how many mediocre workers they employed or how inefficient the techniques they used. The demand was for a vast quantity of war supplies as soon as possible, regardless of cost. Businesses hired every person in sight, even driving sound trucks up and down city streets begging people to apply for jobs. New workers were needed to replace the 11 million working-age men serving in the military. These events magnified the role of the federal government in the national economy. In 1929, federal expenditures accounted for only 3% of GNP. Between 1933 and 1939, federal expenditure tripled, and Roosevelt's critics charged that he was turning America into a [[Socialism|socialist]] state.{{Fact|date=February 2007}} However, spending on the New Deal was far smaller than on the war effort.

==Political consequences==
The crisis had many political consequences, among which was the abandonment of classic [[economic liberalism|economic liberal]] approaches, which








replaced in the United States with Keynesian policies. It was a main factor in the impletation of [[social democracy]] and [[planned economy|planned economies]] in European countries after [[World War II]]. (see [[Marshall Plan]]). Although [[Austrian economists]] had challenged Keynesianism since the 1920s, it was not until 1974, when the [[Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences]] was awarded to [[Friedrich Hayek]] notably for being ''"one of the few economists who gave warning of the possibility of a major economic crisis before the great crash came in the autumn of 1929"'' <ref>[http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1974/press.html ECONOMICS PRIZE FOR WORKS IN ECONOMIC THEORY AND INTER-DISCIPLINARY RESEARCH]</ref>, and the beginning of [[monetarism]], that the Keynesian approach was politically questioned, leading the way to [[neoliberalism]].{{Fact|date=February 2007}}

== Facts and Figures ==
Effects of depression<ref>http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/business/7655472.stm</ref>:
*13 million people became unemployed.
*Industrial production fell by nearly 45% between the years 1929 and 1932.
*Home-building dropped by 80% between the years 1929 and 1932.
*From the years 1929 to 1932, about 5000 banks went out of business.

== Other Great Depressions ==
There have been other downturns called a "Great Depression," but none has been as worldwide for so long. British economic historians use the term "Great depression" to describe British conditions in the late 19th century, especially in agriculture, 1873-1896, a period also referred to as the [[Long Depression]].<ref> T. W. Fletcher, "The Great Depression of English Agriculture 1873-1896," ''The Economic History Review,'' Vol. 13, No. 3 (1961), pp. 417-432 [http://www.jstor.org/stable/2599512 in JSTOR] </ref> Several Latin American countries had severe downturns in the 1980s. Finnish economists refer to the [[Economy of Finland|Finnish economic decline]] around the breakup of the Soviet Union (1989-1994) as a great depression. Kehoe and Prescott define a great depression to be a period of diminished economic output with at least one year where output is 20% below the trend. By this definition [[Economy of Argentina|Argentina]], [[Economic history of Brazil#Stagnation, inflation, and crisis, 1981-94|Brazil]], [[Economy of Chile|Chile]], and [[Economic history of Mexico#1982 Crisis and Recovery|Mexico]] experienced great depressions in the 1980s, and Argentina experienced [[Argentine economic crisis (1999-2002)|another]] in 1998-2002. This definition also includes the economic performance of [[Economy of New Zealand|New Zealand]] from 1974-1992 and [[Economy of Switzerland|Switzerland]] from 1973 to the present, although this designation for Switzerland has been controversial.<ref>{{cite journal|author=Abrahamsen Y, R.; Aeppli, E.; Atukeren, M.; Graff, C.; Müller; Schips, B.|title=The Swiss disease: Facts and artefacts. A reply to Kehoe and Prescott|journal=[[Review of Economic Dynamics]]|volume=8|year=2005|issue=3|pages=749–758|doi=10.1016/j.red.2004.06.003}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|author=Kehoe, T. J.; Ruhl, K. J.|year=2005|title=Is Switzerland in a Great Depression?|publisher=[[Review of Economic Dynamics]]|volume=8|pages=759–775}}</ref>

==See also==
{{multicol}}
*[[Aftermath of World War I]]
*''[[America's Great Depression]]'' written by [[Murray Rothbard]].
*[[Arthurdale]]
*[[Business cycle]]
*[[Cities in the Great Depression]]
*[[Depression cake]]
*[[Economic collapse]]
{{multicol-break}}
*[[Gold as an investment]]
*[[Great Contraction]]
*[[Ivar Kreuger]]
*[[Keynesian economics]]
*[[New Deal]]
*[[Recession]]
*[[Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act]]
*[[Wall Street Crash of 1929]]
{{multicol-end}}

==Notes==
{{reflist|2}}

==Further reading==
{{refbegin}}
* For '''US specific references''', please see complete listing in the [[Great Depression in the United States]] article.
* Ambrosius, G. and W. Hibbard, ''A Social and Economic History of Twentieth-Century Europe'' (1989)
* Bernanke, Ben S. "The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach" ''Journal of Money, Credit & Banking'', Vol. 27, 1995 [http://www.jstor.org/stable/2077848 online at JSTOR]
* Brown, Ian. ''The Economies of Africa and Asia in the inter-war depression'' (1989)
* Davis, Joseph S., ''The World Between the Wars, 1919-39: An Economist's View'' (1974)
* Eichengreen, Barry. ''Golden fetters: The gold standard and the Great Depression, 1919-1939.'' 1992.
* Barry Eichengreen and Marc Flandreau; ''The Gold Standard in Theory and History'' 1997 [http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=109077144 online version]
* Feinstein. Charles H. ''The European economy between the wars'' (1997)
* Friedman, Milton and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. ''A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960'' (1963), monetarist interpretation (heavily statistical)
* Galbraith, John Kenneth, ''The Great Crash, 1929'' (1954)
* Garraty, John A., ''The Great Depression: An Inquiry into the causes, course, and Consequences of the Worldwide Depression of the Nineteen-Thirties, as Seen by Contemporaries and in Light of History'' (1986)
* Garraty John A. ''Unemployment in History'' (1978)
* Garside, William R. ''Capitalism in crisis: international responses to the Great Depression'' (1993)
* Haberler, Gottfried. ''The world economy, money, and the great depression 1919-1939'' (1976)
* Hall Thomas E. and J. David Ferguson. ''The Great Depression: An International Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies'' (1998)
* Kaiser, David E. ''Economic diplomacy and the origins of the Second World War: Germany, Britain, France and Eastern Europe, 1930-1939'' (1980)
* Keynes, John Maynard. "The World's Economic Outlook," ''Atlantic'' (May 1932), [http://www.theatlantic.com/unbound/flashbks/budget/keynesf.htm online edition]
* Kindleberger, Charles P. ''The World in Depression, 1929-1939'' (1983)
* League of Nations, ''World Economic Survey 1932-33'' (1934)
* Madsen, Jakob B. "Trade Barriers and the Collapse of World Trade during the Great Depression", ''Southern Economic Journal'', Southern Economic Journal 2001, 67(4), 848-868 [http://www.jstor.org/stable/1061574 online at JSTOR]
* Mundell, R. A. "A Reconsideration of the Twentieth Century," ''The American Economic Review'' Vol. 90, No. 3 (Jun., 2000), pp. 327–340 [http://www.robertmundell.net/NobelLecture/pdf/A%20RECONSIDERATION%20OF%20THE%20TWENTIETH%20CENTURY.pdf online version]
* Rothermund, Dietmar. ''The Global Impact of the Great Depression'' (1996)
* Tausch, Arno, with Christian Ghymers. "From the “Washington” towards a “Vienna Consensus”? A quantitative analysis on globalization, development and global governance". Hauppauge, N.Y.: Nova Science Publishers, 2007 (for info: https://www.novapublishers.com/catalog/).
* Tausch, Arno and Almas Heshmati (Eds.) "Roadmap to Bangalore? Globalization, the EU’s Lisbon Process and the Structures of Global Inequality" Hauppauge, N.Y.: Nova Science Publishers, 2008, with contributions by Franco Modigliani et al. (for info: https://www.novapublishers.com/catalog/).
* Tipton, F. and R. Aldrich, ''An Economic and Social History of Europe, 1890–1939'' (1987)
{{refend}}


==External links==
==External links==
{{Commonscat}}
{{Commonscat}}
*[http://www.greatdepressionsbook.com Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century, edited by T. J. Kehoe and E. C. Prescott]
*[http://www.southerndomains.com/SouthernBanks/p5.htm Theories of the Great Depression, R. L. Norman, Jr.]
*[http://xroads.virginia.edu/~1930s/front.html America in the 1930s. Very large multi-mediated project on America in the Great Depression]
*[http://economics.about.com/cs/businesscycles/a/depressions.htm Recession? Depression? What's the difference? (About.com)]
*[http://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/parker.depression An Overview of the Great Depression] from EH.NET by Randall Parker.
* [http://www.mackinac.org/archives/1998/sp1998-01.pdf Great Myths of the Great Depression] by [[Lawrence Reed]]
*[http://www.fdrlibrary.marist.edu/gdphotos.html Franklin D. Roosevelt Library & Museum] for copyright-free photos of the period
*[http://www.mises.org/tradcycl/econdepr.asp Economic Depressions: Their Cause and Cure] by [[Murray Rothbard]] (1969)
* [http://www.secondworldwarni.org The Impact of the Great Depression in NI, on the Second World War online resource for NI]
*[http://www.georgiaencyclopedia.org/nge/Article.jsp?id=h-3540&sug=y Great Depression in the Deep South]
*[http://www.capital-flow-analysis.com/investment-essays/migrant_mother.html Migrant Mother, Essay, John Oswin Schroy]

{{GreatDepr nav}}
{{US recessions}}
{{New Deal}}


[[Category:1930s]]
* [http://www.wvec.k12.in.us/McCutcheon/index.html McCutcheon High School]
[[Category:Business cycle]]
* [http://www.lib.purdue.edu/spcol/exhibits/mccutcheon/ McCutcheon Digital Exhibit - Purdue University Libraries Archives and Special Collections]
[[Category:Great Depression| ]]
* [http://libwww.syr.edu/digital/guides/j/JohnTMcCutcheonPapers-Des.htm Syracuse University Libraries]
[[Category:Financial crises]]


[[ar:الكساد الكبير]]
{{DEFAULTSORT:Maccutcheon, John T.}}
[[Category:1870 births]]
[[bs:Velika depresija]]
[[Category:1949 deaths]]
[[ca:Gran depressió]]
[[cs:Velká hospodářská krize]]
[[Category:American cartoonists]]
[[cy:Dirwasgiad Mawr]]
[[Category:People from Chicago, Illinois]]
[[da:Depressionen]]
[[Category:People from Indiana]]
[[de:Weltwirtschaftskrise]]
[[Category:Pulitzer Prize for Editorial Cartooning winners]]
[[et:Suur depressioon]]
[[Category:Purdue University alumni]]
[[es:Gran Depresión]]
[[eo:Granda depresio]]
[[fr:Grande Dépression]]
[[ga:An Spealadh Mór]]
[[gl:Gran Depresión]]
[[ko:대공황]]
[[hr:Velika depresija]]
[[id:Depresi Besar]]
[[is:Kreppan mikla]]
[[it:Grande depressione]]
[[he:השפל הגדול]]
[[ka:დიდი დეპრესია]]
[[la:Depressio oeconomica magna]]
[[lv:Lielā depresija]]
[[lt:Didžioji ekonominė krizė]]
[[hu:Nagy gazdasági világválság]]
[[ms:Zaman Meleset]]
[[nl:Grote Depressie]]
[[ja:世界恐慌]]
[[no:Den store depresjonen]]
[[pl:Wielki kryzys]]
[[pt:Grande Depressão]]
[[ro:Marea criză economică]]
[[ru:Великая депрессия]]
[[simple:Great Depression]]
[[sk:Veľká hospodárska kríza]]
[[sr:Велика криза]]
[[sh:Velika ekonomska kriza]]
[[fi:1930-luvun lama]]
[[sv:Den stora depressionen]]
[[ta:பெரும் பொருளியல் வீழ்ச்சி]]
[[th:ภาวะเศรษฐกิจตกต่ำครั้งใหญ่]]
[[vi:Đại khủng hoảng]]
[[tr:1929 Dünya Ekonomik Bunalımı]]
[[uk:Велика депресія]]
[[yi:וועלט ווירטשאפט קריזיס]]
[[bat-smg:Dėdliuojė akuonuomėnė krėzė]]
[[zh:大萧条]]

Revision as of 22:04, 12 October 2008

Dorothea Lange's Migrant Mother depicts destitute pea pickers in California, centering on Florence Owens Thompson, a mother of seven children, age 32, in Nipomo, California, March 1936.

The Great Depression was a worldwide economic downturn starting in most places in 1929 and ending at different times in the 1930s or early 1940s for different countries. It was the largest and most important economic depression in modern history, and is used in the 21st century as a benchmark on how far the world's economy can fall. The Great Depression originated in the United States; historians most often use as a starting date the stock market crash on October 29, 1929, known as Black Tuesday. The end of the depression in the U.S. is associated with the onset of the war economy of World War II, beginning around 1939.[1]

The depression had devastating effects both in the developed and developing world. International trade was deeply affected, as were personal incomes, tax revenues, prices, and profits. Cities all around the world were hit hard, especially those dependent on heavy industry. Construction was virtually halted in many countries. Farming and rural areas suffered as crop prices fell by 40 to 60 percent.[2][3] Facing plummeting demand with few alternate sources of jobs, areas dependent on primary sector industries such as farming, mining and logging suffered the most.[4] Even shortly after the Wall Street Crash of 1929, optimism persisted. John D. Rockefeller said that "These are days when many are discouraged. In the 93 years of my life, depressions have come and gone. Prosperity has always returned and will again."[5]

The Great Depression ended at different times in different countries; for subsequent history see Home front during World War II. The majority of countries set up relief programs, and most underwent some sort of political upheaval, pushing them to the left or right. In some states, the desperate citizens turned toward nationalist demagogues - the most infamous being Adolf Hitler - setting the stage for World War II in 1939.

The snowball spiral

The Great Depression was not a sudden total collapse. The stock market turned upward in early 1930, returning to early 1929 levels by April, though still almost 30 percent below the peak of September 1929.[6] Together, government and business actually spent more in the first half of 1930 than in the corresponding period of the previous year. But consumers, many of whom had suffered severe losses in the stock market the previous year, cut back their expenditures by ten percent, and a severe drought ravaged the agricultural heartland of the USA beginning in the northern summer of 1930.

In early 1930, credit was ample and available at low rates, but people were reluctant to add new debt by borrowing.[citation needed] By May 1930, auto sales had declined to below the levels of 1928. Prices in general began to decline, but wages held steady in 1930, then began to drop in 1931. Conditions were worst in farming areas, where commodity prices plunged, and in mining and logging areas, where unemployment was high and there were few other jobs. The decline in the American economy was the factor that pulled down most other countries at first, then internal weaknesses or strengths in each country made conditions worse or better. Frantic attempts to shore up the economies of individual nations through protectionist policies, such as the 1930 U.S. Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act and retaliatory tariffs in other countries, exacerbated the collapse in global trade. By late in 1930, a steady decline set in which reached bottom by March 1933.

Causes

There were multiple causes for the first downturn in 1929, including the structural weaknesses and specific events that turned it into a major depression and the way in which the downturn spread from country to country. In relation to the 1929 downturn, historians emphasize structural factors like massive bank failures and the stock market crash, while economists (such as Peter Temin and Barry Eichengreen) point to Britain's decision to return to the Gold Standard at pre-World War I parities (US$4.86:£1).

Recession cycles are thought to be a normal part of living in a world of inexact balances between supply and demand. What turns a usually mild and short recession or "ordinary" business cycle into a great depression is a subject of debate and concern. Scholars have not agreed on the exact causes and their relative importance. The search for causes is closely connected to the question of how to avoid a future depression, and so the political and policy viewpoints of scholars are mixed into the analysis of historic events eight decades ago. The even larger question is whether it was largely a failure on the part of free markets or largely a failure on the part of governments to curtail widespread bank failures, the resulting panics, and reduction in the money supply. Those who believe in a large role for governments in the economy believe it was mostly a failure of the free markets and those who believe in free markets believe it was mostly a failure of government that compounded the problem.

Current theories may be broadly classified into three main points of view. First, there is orthodox classical economics: monetarist, Austrian Economics and neoclassical economic theory, all of which focus on the macroeconomic effects of money supply and the supply of gold which backed many currencies before the Great Depression, including production and consumption.

Chart 1: USA GDP annual pattern and long-term trend, 1920-40, in billions of constant dollars[7].

Second, there are structural theories, most importantly Keynesian, but also including those of institutional economics, that point to underconsumption and overinvestment (economic bubble), malfeasance by bankers and industrialists, or incompetence by government officials. The only consensus viewpoint is that there was a large-scale lack of confidence. Unfortunately, once panic and deflation set in, many people believed they could make more money by keeping clear of the markets as prices got lower and lower and a given amount of money bought ever more goods.

Third, there is the Marxist critique of political economy. This emphasizes contradictions within capital itself (which is viewed as a social relation involving the appropriation of surplus value) as giving rise to an inherently unbalanced dynamic of accumulation resulting in an overaccumulation of capital, culminating in periodic crises of devaluation of capital. The origin of crisis is thus located firmly in the sphere of production, though economic crisis can be aggravated by problems of disproportionality of over-production in the manufacturing and related production sectors and the underconsumption of the masses.

US industrial production (1928-39).

Debt

Crowd at New York's American Union Bank during a bank run early in the Great Depression.

Debt is seen as one of the causes of the Great Depression[8], particularly in the United States[citation needed]. Macroeconomists including Ben Bernanke, the current chairman of the U.S. Federal Reserve Bank, have revived the debt-deflation view[citation needed] of the Great Depression originated by Arthur Cecil Pigou and Irving Fisher:[citation needed] in the 1920s, American consumers and businesses relied on cheap credit[citation needed], the former to purchase consumer goods such as automobiles and furniture, and the latter for capital investment to increase production[citation needed]. This fueled strong short-term growth but created consumer and commercial debt[citation needed]. People and businesses who were deeply in debt when price deflation occurred or demand for their product decreased often risked default[citation needed]. Many drastically cut current spending to keep up time payments, thus lowering demand for new products. Businesses began to fail as construction work and factory orders plunged.

Massive layoffs occurred, resulting in US unemployment rates of over 25% by 1933. Banks which had financed this debt began to fail as debtors defaulted on debt and depositors attempted to withdraw their deposits en masse, triggering multiple bank runs. Government guarantees and Federal Reserve banking regulations to prevent such panics were ineffective or not used. Bank failures led to the loss of billions of dollars in assets.[9] Outstanding debts became heavier, because prices and incomes fell by 20–50% but the debts remained at the same dollar amount. After the panic of 1929, and during the first 10 months of 1930, 744 US banks failed. (In all, 9,000 banks failed during the 1930s). By 1933, depositors had lost $140 billion in deposits.[9]

Bank failures snowballed as desperate bankers called in loans which the borrowers did not have time or money to repay. With future profits looking poor, capital investment and construction slowed or completely ceased. In the face of bad loans and worsening future prospects, the surviving banks became even more conservative in their lending.[9] Banks built up their capital reserves and made fewer loans, which intensified deflationary pressures. A vicious cycle developed and the downward spiral accelerated. This kind of self-aggravating process may have turned a 1930 recession into a 1933 great depression.

Trade decline and the U.S. Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act

Many economists have argued that the sharp decline in international trade after 1930 helped to worsen the depression, especially for countries significantly dependent on foreign trade. Most historians and economists partly blame the American Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act (enacted June 17, 1930) for worsening the depression by seriously reducing international trade and causing retaliatory tariffs in other countries. Foreign trade was a small part of overall economic activity in the United States and was concentrated in a few businesses like farming; it was a much larger factor in many other countries.[10] The average ad valorem rate of duties on dutiable imports for 1921–1925 was 25.9% but under the new tariff it jumped to 50% in 1931–1935.

In dollar terms, American exports declined from about $5.2 billion in 1929 to $1.7 billion in 1933; but prices also fell, so the physical volume of exports only fell by half. Hardest hit were farm commodities such as wheat, cotton, tobacco, and lumber. According to this theory, the collapse of farm exports caused many American farmers to default on their loans, leading to the bank runs on small rural banks that characterized the early years of the Great Depression.

U.S. Federal Reserve and money supply

Monetarists, including Milton Friedman and current Federal Reserve System chairman Ben Bernanke, argue that the Great Depression was caused by monetary contraction, the consequence of poor policymaking by the American Federal Reserve System and continuous crisis in the banking system.[11][12] In this view, the Federal Reserve, by not acting, allowed the money supply as measured by the M2 to shrink by one-third from 1929 to 1933. Friedman argued[13] that the downward turn in the economy, starting with the stock market crash, would have been just another recession. The problem was that some large, public bank failures, particularly that of the Bank of the United States, produced panic and widespread runs on local banks, and that the Federal Reserve sat idly by while banks fell. He claimed that, if the Fed had provided emergency lending to these key banks, or simply bought government bonds on the open market to provide liquidity and increase the quantity of money after the key banks fell, all the rest of the banks would not have fallen after the large ones did, and the money supply would not have fallen as far and as fast as it did.[14] With significantly less money to go around, businessmen could not get new loans and could not even get their old loans renewed, forcing many to stop investing. This interpretation blames the Federal Reserve for inaction, especially the New York branch.[15]

One reason why the Federal Reserve did not act to limit the decline of the money supply was regulation. At that time the amount of credit the Federal Reserve could issue was limited by laws which required partial gold backing of that credit. By the late 1920s the Federal Reserve had almost hit the limit of allowable credit that could be backed by the gold in its possession. This credit was in the form of Federal Reserve demand notes. Since a "promise of gold" is not as good as "gold in the hand", during the bank panics a portion of those demand notes were redeemed for Federal Reserve gold. Since the Federal Reserve had hit its limit on allowable credit, any reduction in gold in its vaults had to be accompanied by a greater reduction in credit. Several years into the Great Depression, the private ownership of gold was declared illegal, reducing the pressure on Federal Reserve gold.

Austrian School explanations

Another explanation comes from the Austrian School of economics. Theorists of the "Austrian School" who wrote about the Depression include Austrian economist Friedrich Hayek and American economist Murray Rothbard, who wrote America's Great Depression (1963). In their view, the key cause of the Depression was the expansion of the money supply in the 1920s that led to an unsustainable credit-driven boom. In their view, the Federal Reserve, which was created in 1913, shoulders much of the blame.

In opinion, Hayek, writing for the Austrian Institute of Economic Research Report in February 1929[16] predicted the economic downturn, stating that "the boom will collapse within the next few months."

Ludwig von Mises also expected this financial catastrophe, and is quoted as stating "A great crash is coming, and I don't want my name in any way connected with it,"[17] when he turned down an important job at the Kreditanstalt Bank in early 1929.

One reason for the monetary inflation was to help Great Britain, which, in the 1920s, was struggling with its plans to return to the gold standard at pre-war (World War I) parity. Returning to the gold standard at this rate meant that the British economy was facing deflationary pressure.[18] According to Rothbard, the lack of price flexibility in Britain meant that unemployment shot up, and the American government was asked to help. The United States was receiving a net inflow of gold, and inflated further in order to help Britain return to the gold standard. Montagu Norman, head of the Bank of England, had an especially good relationship with Benjamin Strong, the de facto head of the Federal Reserve. Norman pressured the heads of the central banks of France and Germany to inflate as well, but unlike Strong, they refused.[18] Rothbard says American inflation was meant to allow Britain to inflate as well, because under the gold standard, Britain could not inflate on its own.

In the Austrian view it was this inflation of the money supply that led to an unsustainable boom in both asset prices (stocks and bonds) and capital goods. By the time the Fed belatedly tightened in 1928, it was far too late and, in the Austrian view, a depression was inevitable.

The artificial interference in the economy was a disaster prior to the Depression, and government efforts to prop up the economy after the crash of 1929 only made things worse. According to Rothbard, government intervention delayed the market's adjustment and made the road to complete recovery more difficult.[19]

Furthermore, Rothbard criticizes Milton Friedman's assertion that the central bank failed to inflate the supply of money. Rothbard asserts that the Federal Reserve bought $1.1 billion of government securities from February to July 1932, raising its total holding to $1.8 billion. Total bank reserves rose by only $212 million, but Rothbard argues that this was because the American populace lost faith in the banking system and began hoarding more cash, a factor quite beyond the control of the Central Bank. The potential for a run on the banks caused local bankers to be more conservative in lending out their reserves, and this, Rothbard argues, was the cause of the Federal Reserve's inability to inflate.[20]

Power farming displaces tenants from the land in the western dry cotton area. Childress County, Texas, 1938.

Business

Franklin D. Roosevelt, elected in 1932, primarily blamed the excesses of big business for causing an unstable bubble-like economy. Democrats believed the problem was that business had too much money, and the New Deal was intended as a remedy, by empowering labor unions and farmers and by raising taxes on corporate profits. Regulation of the economy was a favorite remedy. Some New Deal regulation (the NRA and AAA) was declared unconstitutional by the U.S. Supreme Court. Most New Deal regulations were abolished or scaled back in the 1970s and 1980s in a bipartisan wave of deregulation.[21] However the Securities and Exchange Commission, Federal Reserve, and Social Security won widespread support.

Lack of government deficit spending

British economist John Maynard Keynes argued in General Theory of Employment Interest and Money that lower aggregate expenditures in the economy contributed to a massive decline in income and to employment that was well below the average. In this situation, the economy might have reached a perfect balance, at a cost of high unemployment. Keynesian economists called on governments during times of economic crisis to pick up the slack by increasing government spending and/or cutting taxes.

Massive increases in deficit spending, new banking regulation, and boosting farm prices did start turning the U.S. economy around in 1933,[citation needed] but it was a slow and painful process. The U.S. had not returned to 1929's GNP for over a decade and still had an unemployment rate of about 15% in 1940 — down from 25% in 1933.

Inequality of wealth and income

Marriner S. Eccles, who served as Franklin D. Roosevelt's Chairman of the Federal Reserve from November 1934 to February 1948, detailed what he believed caused the Depression in his memoirs, Beckoning Frontiers (New York, Alfred A. Knopf, 1951)[22]:

As mass production has to be accompanied by mass consumption, mass consumption, in turn, implies a distribution of wealth -- not of existing wealth, but of wealth as it is currently produced -- to provide men with buying power equal to the amount of goods and services offered by the nation's economic machinery. [Emphasis in original.]

Instead of achieving that kind of distribution, a giant suction pump had by 1929-30 drawn into a few hands an increasing portion of currently produced wealth. This served them as capital accumulations. But by taking purchasing power out of the hands of mass consumers, the savers denied to themselves the kind of effective demand for their products that would justify a reinvestment of their capital accumulations in new plants. In consequence, as in a poker game where the chips were concentrated in fewer and fewer hands, the other fellows could stay in the game only by borrowing. When their credit ran out, the game stopped.

That is what happened to us in the twenties. We sustained high levels of employment in that period with the aid of an exceptional expansion of debt outside of the banking system. This debt was provided by the large growth of business savings as well as savings by individuals, particularly in the upper-income groups where taxes were relatively low. Private debt outside of the banking system increased about fifty per cent. This debt, which was at high interest rates, largely took the form of mortgage debt on housing, office, and hotel structures, consumer installment debt, brokers' loans, and foreign debt. The stimulation to spend by debt-creation of this sort was short-lived and could not be counted on to sustain high levels of employment for long periods of time. Had there been a better distribution of the current income from the national product -- in other words, had there been less savings by business and the higher-income groups and more income in the lower groups -- we should have had far greater stability in our economy. Had the six billion dollars, for instance, that were loaned by corporations and wealthy individuals for stock-market speculation been distributed to the public as lower prices or higher wages and with less profits to the corporations and the well-to-do, it would have prevented or greatly moderated the economic collapse that began at the end of 1929.

The time came when there were no more poker chips to be loaned on credit. Debtors thereupon were forced to curtail their consumption in an effort to create a margin that could be applied to the reduction of outstanding debts. This naturally reduced the demand for goods of all kinds and brought on what seemed to be overproduction, but was in reality underconsumption when judged in terms of the real world instead of the money world. This, in turn, brought about a fall in prices and employment.

Unemployment further decreased the consumption of goods, which further increased unemployment, thus closing the circle in a continuing decline of prices. Earnings began to disappear, requiring economies of all kinds in the wages, salaries, and time of those employed. And thus again the vicious circle of deflation was closed until one third of the entire working population was unemployed, with our national income reduced by fifty per cent, and with the aggregate debt burden greater than ever before, not in dollars, but measured by current values and income that represented the ability to pay. Fixed charges, such as taxes, railroad and other utility rates, insurance and interest charges, clung close to the 1929 level and required such a portion of the national income to meet them that the amount left for consumption of goods was not sufficient to support the population.

This then, was my reading of what brought on the depression.

Literature

The U.S. Depression has been the subject of much writing, as the country has sought to re-evaluate an era that caused emotional as well as financial trauma to its people. Perhaps the most noteworthy and famous novel written on the subject is The Grapes of Wrath, published in 1939 and written by John Steinbeck, who was awarded both the Nobel Prize for literature and the Pulitzer Prize for the work. The novel focuses on a poor family of sharecroppers who are forced from their home as drought, economic hardship, and changes in the agricultural industry occur during the Great Depression. Steinbeck's Of Mice and Men is another important novel about a journey during the Great Depression. The Great Depression is a novella written by Alon Bersharder about a sad, disgruntled temporary worker, making the title both a homage to the historical event and a pun. Additionally, Harper Lee's To Kill a Mockingbird is set during the Great Depression. Margaret Atwood's Booker prize-winning The Blind Assassin is likewise set in the Great Depression, centering on a privileged socialite's love affair with a Marxist revolutionary.

Effects

Australia

Australia's extreme dependence on agricultural and industrial exports meant it was one of the hardest-hit countries in the Western world, amongst the likes of Canada and Germany. Falling export demand and commodity prices placed massive downward pressures on wages. Further, unemployment reached a record high of almost 32% in 1932, with incidents of civil unrest becoming common. After 1932, an increase in wool and meat prices led to a gradual recovery.

Canada

Unemployed men march in Toronto, Ontario, Canada.

Harshly impacted by both the global economic downturn and the Dust Bowl, Canadian industrial production had fallen to only 58% of the 1929 level by 1932, the second lowest level in the world after the United States, and well behind nations such as Britain, which saw it fall only to 83% of the 1929 level. Total national income fell to 55% of the 1929 level, again worse than any nation apart from the United States.

France

The Depression began to affect France from about 1931. France's relatively high degree of self-sufficiency meant the damage was considerably less than in nations like Germany. However, hardship and unemployment were high enough to lead to rioting and the rise of the socialist Popular Front.

Germany

Germany's Weimar Republic was hit hard by the depression, as American loans to help rebuild the German economy now stopped. Unemployment soared, especially in larger cities, and the political system veered toward extremism. Repayment of the war reparations due by Germany were suspended in 1932 following the Lausanne Conference of 1932. By that time Germany had repaid 1/8th of the reparations. Hitler's Nazi Party came to power in January 1933.

Japan

The Great Depression did not strongly affect Japan. The Japanese economy shrank by 8% during 1929–31. However, Japan was fortunate to have far sighted Minister of Finance (MoF) Osachi Hamaguchi at the time who implemented the first version of Keynesian economic policies: first, by increasing deficit spending; and second, by devaluing the currency. The MoF believed that the deficit spending could easily be paid for when productivity improved.

The devaluation of the currency had an immediate effect. Quickly, Japanese textiles began to displace British textiles in export markets. The deficit spending, however proved to be most profound. The deficit spending went into the purchase of munitions for the armed forces. By 1933, Japan was already out of the depression. By 1934 the MoF realized that the economy was in danger of overheating, and to avoid inflation, moved to reduce the deficit spending that went towards armaments and munitions. This resulted in a strong and swift negative reaction from nationalists, especially those in the Army, culminating in the assassination of the MoF. This had a chilling effect on all civilian bureaucrats in the Japanese government. From 1934, the military's dominance of the government continued to grow. Instead of reducing deficit spending, the government introduced price controls and rationing schemes that reduced, but did not eliminate inflation, which would remain a problem until the end of World War II.

The deficit spending had a transformative effect on Japan. Japan's industrial production doubled during the 1930s. Further, in 1929 the list of the largest firms in Japan was dominated by light industries, especially textile companies (many of Japan's automakers, like Toyota, have their roots in the textile industry). By 1940 light industry had been displaced by heavy industry as the largest firms inside the Japanese economy. (For more on the Japanese economy in the 1930s see "MITI and the Japanese Miracle" by Chalmers Johnson).

These events obviously set the stage for World War II. In 1929, Japan's GNP was about a sixth of the U.S. and its per capita GNP was about a third. However, during the 1930s, the U.S. economy contracted by a third. By 1939, Japan's GNP was nearly half that of the United States, and its per capita GNP was nearly equal to the United States. Face with having to face two Oceans, it was easy to see how some Japanese planners felt that they had an even chance against the U.S. What they may not have considered is that the U.S. had yet to truly kick in deficit financing for munitions until after 1940 - where upon the United States would experience its own doubling of industrial production in four short years.

Latin America

Because of high levels of United States investment in Latin American economies, they were severely damaged by the Depression. Within the region, Chile, Bolivia and Peru were particularly badly affected. One result of the Depression in this area was the rise of fascist movements.[citation needed]

Netherlands

From roughly 1931 until 1937, the Netherlands suffered a deep and exceptionally long depression. This depression was partly caused by the after-effects of the Stock Market Crash of 1929 in the United States, and partly by internal factors in the Netherlands. Government policy, especially the very late dropping of the Gold Standard, played a role in prolonging the depression. The Great Depression in the Netherlands led to some political instability and riots, and can be linked to the rise of the Dutch national-socialist party NSB. The depression in the Netherlands eased off somewhat at the end of 1936, when the government finally dropped the Gold Standard, but real economic stability did not return until after World War II.

South Africa

As world trade slumped, demand for South African agricultural and mineral exports fell drastically. It is believed that the social discomfort caused by the depression was a contributing factor in the 1933 split between the "gesuiwerde" (purified) and "smelter" (fusionist) factions within the National Party and the National Party's subsequent fusion with the South African Party.

Soviet Union

Having removed itself from the capitalist world system both by choice and as a result of efforts of the capitalist powers to isolate it, the Great Depression had little effect on the Soviet Union. This was a period of industrial expansion for the USSR as it recovered from revolution and civil war, and its apparent immunity to the Great Depression seemed to validate the theory of Marxism and contributed to Socialist and Communist agitation in affected nations. This in turn increased fears of Communist revolution in the West, strengthening support for anti-Communists, both moderate and extreme.

United Kingdom

United States

Early response

Secretary of the Treasury Andrew Mellon advised President Hoover that shock treatment would be the best response: "Liquidate labor, liquidate stocks, liquidate the farmers, liquidate real estate.... That will purge the rottenness out of the system. High costs of living and high living will come down. People will work harder, live a more moral life. Values will be adjusted, and enterprising people will pick up the wrecks from less competent people."[23] Hoover rejected this advice, and started numerous programs, all of which failed to reverse the downturn.[24]

Hoover launched a series of programs to increase farm prices, which failed, expanded federal spending in public works such as dams, and launched the Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC) which aided cities, banks and railroads, and continued as a major agency under the New Deal. To provide unemployment relief he set up the Emergency Relief Agency (ERA) that operated until 1935 as the Federal Emergency Relief Agency. Quarter by quarter the economy went downhill, as prices, profits and employment fell, leading to the political realignment in 1932 that brought to power the New Deal.

GDP in constant (2000) dollars

The New Deal

Shortly after President Roosevelt was inaugurated in 1933, drought and erosion combined to cause the Dust Bowl, shifting hundreds of thousands of displaced persons off their farms in the midwest. From his inauguration onward, Roosevelt argued that restructuring of the economy would be needed to prevent another depression or avoid prolonging the current one. New Deal programs sought to stimulate demand and provide work and relief for the impoverished through increased government spending and institute financial reforms. The Securities Act of 1933 comprehensively regulated the securities industry. This was followed by the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 which created the Securities and Exchange Commission. Though amended, key provisions of both Acts are still in force. Federal insurance of bank deposits was provided by the FDIC, and the Glass-Steagall Act. The institution of the National Recovery Administration (NRA) remains a controversial act to this day. The NRA made a number of sweeping changes to the American economy until it was deemed unconstitutional by the Supreme Court of the United States in 1935.

Early changes by the Roosevelt administration included:

  • Instituting regulations to fight deflationary "cut-throat competition" through the NRA.
  • Setting minimum prices and wages, labor standards, and competitive conditions in all industries through the NRA.
  • Encouraging unions that would raise wages, to increase the purchasing power of the working class.
  • Cutting farm production to raise prices through the Agricultural Adjustment Act and its successors.
  • Forcing businesses to work with government to set price codes through the NRA.

These reforms, together with several other relief and recovery measures are called the First New Deal. New regulations and attempts at economic stimulus through a new alphabet soup of agencies set up in 1933 and 1934 and previously extant agencies such as the Reconstruction Finance Corporation did not halt economic stagnation. By 1935, the "Second New Deal" added Social Security, a national relief agency (the Works Progress Administration, WPA) and, through the National Labor Relations Board, a strong stimulus to the growth of labor unions. Unemployment declined by over one-third in Roosevelt's first term (from 25% to 14.3%, 1933 to 1937), but faster than the economic upturn came 1938's "recession within a depression" and unemployment zoomed to 19%, then declined somewhat until the draft to fight World War II lowered it more. In 1929, federal expenditures constituted only 3% of the GDP. Expenditures as a proportion of GDP tripled[citation needed] between 1933 and 1939, accompanied by sizable deficits.[citation needed] The debt as a proportion of GNP rose under Hoover from 20% to 40%. Roosevelt kept it at 40% until the war began, when it soared to 128%. After the Recession of 1937, conservatives were able to form a bipartisan conservative coalition to stop further expansion of the New Deal and, by 1943, had abolished all of the relief programs. In 1946, large-scale relaxation of government controls[citation needed] over the wartime economy, including a sharp reduction of taxes, allowed for increased innovation in consumer goods and a marked increase in consumer spending. Unemployment rates also returned to normal levels.[citation needed]

Recession of 1937

In 1937 the American economy took an unexpected nosedive, lasting through most of 1938. Production declined sharply, as did profits and employment. Unemployment jumped from 14.3% in 1937 to 19.0% in 1938. The Roosevelt administration reacted by launching a rhetorical campaign against monopoly power, which was cast as the cause of the depression, and by appointing Thurman Arnold to act; Arnold's effectiveness ended once World War II began and corporate energies had to be directed to winning the war.

The administration's other response to the 1937 deepening of the Great Depression had more tangible results. Ignoring the pleas of the Treasury Department, Roosevelt embarked on an antidote to the depression, reluctantly abandoning his efforts to balance the budget and launching a $5 billion spending program in the spring of 1938, an effort to increase mass purchasing power. Business-oriented observers explained the recession and recovery in very different terms from the Keynesians. They argued that the New Deal had been very hostile to business expansion in 1935–37, had encouraged massive strikes which had a negative impact on major industries such as automobiles, and had threatened massive antitrust legal attacks on big corporations. All those threats diminished sharply after 1938. For example, the antitrust efforts fizzled out without major cases. The CIO and AFL unions started battling each other more than with the corporations, and tax policy became more favorable to long-term growth, according to this argument.

On the other hand, according to economist Robert Higgs, when looking only at the supply of consumer goods, significant GDP growth resumed only in 1946 (Higgs does not estimate the value to consumers of collective, intangible goods like victory in war). To Keynesians, the war economy showed just how large the fiscal stimulus required to end the downturn of the Depression was, and it led, at the time, to fears that as soon as America demobilized, it would return to Depression conditions, and industrial output would fall to pre-war levels. That incorrect Keynesian prediction that a new depression would start after the war failed to take into account massive savings and pent-up consumer demand, along with the ending of the restrictive wartime regulations in most consumer industries, and the cutting of high tax rates starting in 1946. In any case, government spending and changing regulations (first tightening them, then loosening them) appear to have contributed to the recovery, as consumer and producer behavior changed.

Keynesian models

In the early 1930s, before John Maynard Keynes wrote The General Theory, he was advocating public works programs and deficits as a way to get the British economy out of the Depression. Although Keynes never mentions fiscal policy in The General Theory, and instead advocates the need to socialize investments, Keynes ushered in more of a theoretical revolution than a policy one. His basic idea was simple: to keep people fully employed, governments have to run deficits when the economy is slowing because the private sector will not invest enough to increase production and reverse the recession.

As the Depression wore on, Roosevelt tried public works, farm subsidies, and other devices to restart the economy, but never completely gave up trying to balance the budget. According to the Keynesians, he needed to spend much more money; they were unable to say how much more. With fiscal policy, however, government could provide the needed Keynesian spending by decreasing taxes, increasing government spending, and increasing individuals' incomes. As incomes increased, they would spend more. As they spent more, the multiplier effect would take over and expand the effect on the initial spending. The Keynesians did not estimate what the size of the multiplier was. Keynesian economists assumed poor people would spend new incomes; however, they saved much of the new money; that is, they paid back debts owed to landlords, grocers and family [citation needed], which might have then spent the money. Keynesian ideas of the consumption function have been challenged, most notably in the 1950s by Milton Friedman and Franco Modigliani.

Neoclassical approach

Recent work from a neoclassical perspective focuses on the decline in productivity that caused the initial decline in output and a prolonged recovery due to policies that affected the labor market. This work, collected by Kehoe and Prescott,[25] decomposes the economic decline into a decline in the labor force, capital stock, and the productivity with which these inputs are used. This study suggests that theories of the Great Depression have to explain an initial severe decline but rapid recovery in productivity, relatively little change in the capital stock, and a prolonged depression in the labor force. This analysis rejects theories that focus on the role of savings and posit a decline in the capital stock.

Gold standard

Every major currency left the gold standard during the Great Depression. Great Britain was the first to do so. Facing speculative attacks on the pound and depleting gold reserves, in September 1931 the Bank of England ceased exchanging pound notes for gold and the pound was floated on foreign exchange markets.

Great Britain, Japan, and the Scandinavian countries left the gold standard in 1931. Other countries, such as Italy and the United States, remained on the gold standard into 1932 or 1933, while a few countries in the so-called "gold bloc", led by France and including Poland, Belgium and Switzerland, stayed on the standard until 1935-1936.

According to later analysis, the earliness with which a country left the gold standard reliably predicted its economic recovery. For example, Great Britain and Scandinavia, which left the gold standard in 1931, recovered much earlier than France and Belgium, which remained on gold much longer. Countries such as China, which had a silver standard, almost avoided the depression entirely. The connection between leaving the gold standard as a strong predictor of that country's severity of its depression and the length of time of its recovery has been shown to be consistent for dozens of countries, including developing countries. This partly explains why the experience and length of the depression differed between national economies [26].

Rearmament and recovery

The massive rearmament policies to counter the threat from Nazi Germany helped stimulate the economies of Europe in 1937-39. By 1937, unemployment in Britain had fallen to 1.5 million. The mobilization of manpower following the outbreak of war in 1939 finally ended unemployment.

In the United States, the massive war spending doubled the GNP, either masking the effects of the Depression or essentially ending the Depression. Businessmen ignored the mounting national debt and heavy new taxes, redoubling their efforts for greater output to take advantage of generous government contracts. Productivity soared: most people worked overtime and gave up leisure activities to make money after so many hard years. People accepted rationing and price controls for the first time as a way of expressing their support for the war effort. Cost-plus pricing in munitions contracts guaranteed businesses a profit no matter how many mediocre workers they employed or how inefficient the techniques they used. The demand was for a vast quantity of war supplies as soon as possible, regardless of cost. Businesses hired every person in sight, even driving sound trucks up and down city streets begging people to apply for jobs. New workers were needed to replace the 11 million working-age men serving in the military. These events magnified the role of the federal government in the national economy. In 1929, federal expenditures accounted for only 3% of GNP. Between 1933 and 1939, federal expenditure tripled, and Roosevelt's critics charged that he was turning America into a socialist state.[citation needed] However, spending on the New Deal was far smaller than on the war effort.

Political consequences

The crisis had many political consequences, among which was the abandonment of classic economic liberal approaches, which





replaced in the United States with Keynesian policies. It was a main factor in the impletation of social democracy and planned economies in European countries after World War II. (see Marshall Plan). Although Austrian economists had challenged Keynesianism since the 1920s, it was not until 1974, when the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences was awarded to Friedrich Hayek notably for being "one of the few economists who gave warning of the possibility of a major economic crisis before the great crash came in the autumn of 1929" [27], and the beginning of monetarism, that the Keynesian approach was politically questioned, leading the way to neoliberalism.[citation needed]

Facts and Figures

Effects of depression[28]:

  • 13 million people became unemployed.
  • Industrial production fell by nearly 45% between the years 1929 and 1932.
  • Home-building dropped by 80% between the years 1929 and 1932.
  • From the years 1929 to 1932, about 5000 banks went out of business.

Other Great Depressions

There have been other downturns called a "Great Depression," but none has been as worldwide for so long. British economic historians use the term "Great depression" to describe British conditions in the late 19th century, especially in agriculture, 1873-1896, a period also referred to as the Long Depression.[29] Several Latin American countries had severe downturns in the 1980s. Finnish economists refer to the Finnish economic decline around the breakup of the Soviet Union (1989-1994) as a great depression. Kehoe and Prescott define a great depression to be a period of diminished economic output with at least one year where output is 20% below the trend. By this definition Argentina, Brazil, Chile, and Mexico experienced great depressions in the 1980s, and Argentina experienced another in 1998-2002. This definition also includes the economic performance of New Zealand from 1974-1992 and Switzerland from 1973 to the present, although this designation for Switzerland has been controversial.[30][31]

See also

Template:Multicol

Template:Multicol-break

Template:Multicol-end

Notes

  1. ^ L. Engerman, Stanley. The Cambridge Economic History of the United States. {{cite book}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  2. ^ Cochrane, Willard W. (1958). "Farm Prices, Myth and Reality": 15. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  3. ^ "World Economic Survey 1932–33". League of Nations: 43.
  4. ^ Hakim, Joy (1995). A History of Us: War, Peace and all that Jazz. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19509484-0..
  5. ^ Schultz, Stanley K. (1999). "Crashing Hopes: The Great Depression". American History 102: Civil War to the Present. University of Wisconsin-Madison. Retrieved 2008-03-13..
  6. ^ "1998/99 Prognosis Based Upon 1929 Market Autopsy". Gold Eagle. Retrieved 2008-05-22..
  7. ^ Carter, Susan (2006). Historical Statistics of the US: Millennial Edition.
  8. ^ http://encarta.msn.com/encyclopedia_761584403/Great_Depression_in_the_United_States.html#s11
  9. ^ a b c "Bank Failures". Living History Farm. Retrieved 2008-05-22.
  10. ^ "The World in Depression". Mount Holyoke College. Retrieved 2008-05-22.
  11. ^ Bernanke, Ben S. (2000). Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton University Press. p. 7. ISBN 0691016984.
  12. ^ "Bernanke: Federal Reserve caused Great Depression". WorldNetDaily. Retrieved 2008-03-21.
  13. ^ A Monetary History of the United States.
  14. ^ Krugman, Paul (2007-02-15). "Who Was Milton Friedman?". The New York Review of Books. Retrieved 2008-05-22.
  15. ^ Griffin, G. Edward (2002). The Creature from Jekyll Island: A Second Look at the Federal Reserve. American Media (publisher). ISBN 0912986395. {{cite book}}: Unknown parameter |isbn-13= ignored (help)
  16. ^ "Austrian Institute of Economic Research Report". 1929. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help); Unknown parameter |month= ignored (help)
  17. ^ Mises, Margit von (1976). My Years with Ludwig von Mises. Arlington House. p. 31.
  18. ^ a b Rothbard 2002, p. 141
  19. ^ Rothbard 2002, p. 25
  20. ^ Rothbard 2002, pp. 293–294
  21. ^ Vietor, Richard H. K. (1994). Contrived Competition: Regulation and Deregulation in America.
  22. ^ Eccles, Marriner S. (1951). Beckoning Frontiers: Public and Personal Recollections (1st ed.). New York: Alfred A. Knopf. p. 499. OCLC 3720103.
  23. ^ Hoover, Herbert. "3:9". The memoirs of Herbert Hoover.
  24. ^ Waren, Herbert Hoover and the Great Depression
  25. ^ Kehoe, Timothy J.; Prescott, Edward C. (2007). Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  26. ^ Bernanke, Ben (March 2, 2004), "Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke: Money, Gold and the Great Depression", At the H. Parker Willis Lecture in Economic Policy, Washington and Lee University, Lexington, Virginia
  27. ^ ECONOMICS PRIZE FOR WORKS IN ECONOMIC THEORY AND INTER-DISCIPLINARY RESEARCH
  28. ^ http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/business/7655472.stm
  29. ^ T. W. Fletcher, "The Great Depression of English Agriculture 1873-1896," The Economic History Review, Vol. 13, No. 3 (1961), pp. 417-432 in JSTOR
  30. ^ Abrahamsen Y, R.; Aeppli, E.; Atukeren, M.; Graff, C.; Müller; Schips, B. (2005). "The Swiss disease: Facts and artefacts. A reply to Kehoe and Prescott". Review of Economic Dynamics. 8 (3): 749–758. doi:10.1016/j.red.2004.06.003.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  31. ^ Kehoe, T. J.; Ruhl, K. J. (2005). "Is Switzerland in a Great Depression?". 8. Review of Economic Dynamics: 759–775. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)

Further reading

  • For US specific references, please see complete listing in the Great Depression in the United States article.
  • Ambrosius, G. and W. Hibbard, A Social and Economic History of Twentieth-Century Europe (1989)
  • Bernanke, Ben S. "The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach" Journal of Money, Credit & Banking, Vol. 27, 1995 online at JSTOR
  • Brown, Ian. The Economies of Africa and Asia in the inter-war depression (1989)
  • Davis, Joseph S., The World Between the Wars, 1919-39: An Economist's View (1974)
  • Eichengreen, Barry. Golden fetters: The gold standard and the Great Depression, 1919-1939. 1992.
  • Barry Eichengreen and Marc Flandreau; The Gold Standard in Theory and History 1997 online version
  • Feinstein. Charles H. The European economy between the wars (1997)
  • Friedman, Milton and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960 (1963), monetarist interpretation (heavily statistical)
  • Galbraith, John Kenneth, The Great Crash, 1929 (1954)
  • Garraty, John A., The Great Depression: An Inquiry into the causes, course, and Consequences of the Worldwide Depression of the Nineteen-Thirties, as Seen by Contemporaries and in Light of History (1986)
  • Garraty John A. Unemployment in History (1978)
  • Garside, William R. Capitalism in crisis: international responses to the Great Depression (1993)
  • Haberler, Gottfried. The world economy, money, and the great depression 1919-1939 (1976)
  • Hall Thomas E. and J. David Ferguson. The Great Depression: An International Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies (1998)
  • Kaiser, David E. Economic diplomacy and the origins of the Second World War: Germany, Britain, France and Eastern Europe, 1930-1939 (1980)
  • Keynes, John Maynard. "The World's Economic Outlook," Atlantic (May 1932), online edition
  • Kindleberger, Charles P. The World in Depression, 1929-1939 (1983)
  • League of Nations, World Economic Survey 1932-33 (1934)
  • Madsen, Jakob B. "Trade Barriers and the Collapse of World Trade during the Great Depression", Southern Economic Journal, Southern Economic Journal 2001, 67(4), 848-868 online at JSTOR
  • Mundell, R. A. "A Reconsideration of the Twentieth Century," The American Economic Review Vol. 90, No. 3 (Jun., 2000), pp. 327–340 online version
  • Rothermund, Dietmar. The Global Impact of the Great Depression (1996)
  • Tausch, Arno, with Christian Ghymers. "From the “Washington” towards a “Vienna Consensus”? A quantitative analysis on globalization, development and global governance". Hauppauge, N.Y.: Nova Science Publishers, 2007 (for info: https://www.novapublishers.com/catalog/).
  • Tausch, Arno and Almas Heshmati (Eds.) "Roadmap to Bangalore? Globalization, the EU’s Lisbon Process and the Structures of Global Inequality" Hauppauge, N.Y.: Nova Science Publishers, 2008, with contributions by Franco Modigliani et al. (for info: https://www.novapublishers.com/catalog/).
  • Tipton, F. and R. Aldrich, An Economic and Social History of Europe, 1890–1939 (1987)

External links