Laissez-faire: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
No edit summary
m Added link
 
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Economic system}}
{{combi}}
{{italic title}}
{{unreferenced|date=November 2006}}
{{economic systems sidebar|by ideology}}
|{{Libertarianism}}
{{Capitalism sidebar}}
|-
{{neoliberalism sidebar}}
|{{liberalism}}
{{liberalism sidebar}}
|}
{{libertarianism sidebar}}
'''Laissez-faire''' ({{IPA2|lɛse fɛr}}) or '''laisser-faire''' is short for ''laissez faire, laissez aller, laissez passer'', a [[French language|French]] phrase meaning "let do, let go, let pass." From the French diction first used by the eighteenth century [[physiocrats]] as an injunction against government interference with trade, it became used as a synonym for strict [[free market]] [[economics]] during the early and mid-[[19th century]]. It is generally understood to be a doctrine that maintains that private initiative and production is best to roam free, opposing [[economic interventionism]] and [[taxation]] by the state beyond that which is perceived to be necessary to maintain peace, security, and property rights.<ref name="Hanlin">{{cite journal|author=Oscar Handlin|title=Laissez-Faire thought in Massachusetts, 1790-1880|year=1943|journal=Journal of Economic History|volume=3|pages=55-65}}</ref> (Some extreme laissez-faire advocates even oppose taxation). It also embodies [[free trade]], namely that a state should not use [[protectionism|protectionist measures]], such as [[tariff]]s, in order to curtail trade between nations.
'''''Laissez-faire''''' ({{IPAc-en|ˌ|l|ɛ|s|eɪ|ˈ|f|ɛər}} {{respell|LESS|ay|FAIR}}; from {{lang-fr|link=no|laissez faire}} {{IPA-fr|lɛse fɛːʁ||fr-Laissez-faire.oga}}, {{lit.|let do}}) is a type of [[economic system]] in which transactions between private groups of people are free from any form of [[economic interventionism]] (such as [[Subsidy|subsidies]] or [[Regulatory economics|regulations]]). As a system of thought, ''laissez-faire'' rests on the following axioms: "the individual is the basic unit in society, i.e., the standard of measurement in social calculus; the individual has a natural right to freedom; and the physical order of nature is a harmonious and self-regulating system."<ref name="Gaspard, Toufick 2004"/> The original phrase was '''''laissez faire, laissez passer''''', with the second part meaning "let (things) pass". It is generally attributed to [[Vincent de Gournay]].<ref name="WilsonReill2004">{{cite book |author1=Ellen Judy Wilson |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=t1pQ4YG-TDIC&pg=PA241 |title=Encyclopedia Of The Enlightenment |author2=Peter Hanns Reill |date=1 August 2004 |publisher=Infobase Publishing |isbn=978-0-8160-5335-3 |page=241 |access-date=21 July 2012 |archive-date=23 July 2023 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230723114704/https://books.google.com/books?id=t1pQ4YG-TDIC&pg=PA241 |url-status=live }}</ref>


Another basic principle of ''laissez-faire'' holds that markets should naturally be [[Competition (economics)|competitive]], a rule that the early advocates of ''laissez-faire'' always emphasized.<ref name="Gaspard, Toufick 2004"/>
In the early stages of European and American [[economics|economic]] theory, laissez-faire economic policy was contrasted to ''[[mercantilism|mercantilist]]'' economic policy, which had been the dominant system of the United Kingdom, Spain, France and other European countries, during their rise to power.


The [[Physiocracy|Physiocrats]] were early advocates of ''laissez-faire'' and advocated for a ''impôt unique'', a [[land value tax|tax on land rent]] to replace the "monstrous and crippling network of taxation that had grown up in 17th century France".<ref>{{Cite book |last=Rothbard |first=Murray |title=An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought |publisher=Edward Elgar Publishing |year=1995 |isbn=0-945466-48-X |page=371}}</ref> Their view was that only land should be taxed because land is not produced but a naturally existing resource, meaning a tax on it wouldn't be taking from the labour of the taxed, unlike most other taxes.<ref>{{cite web|last1=Gaffney|first1=Mason|title=The Taxable Surplus of Land: Measuring, Guarding and Gathering It|url=http://schalkenbach.org/on-line-library/works-by-m-mason-gaffney-2/the-taxable-surplus-of-land-measuring-guarding-and-gathering-it/|access-date=9 December 2014|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150510094457/http://schalkenbach.org/on-line-library/works-by-m-mason-gaffney-2/the-taxable-surplus-of-land-measuring-guarding-and-gathering-it/|archive-date=10 May 2015}}</ref>{{Clarify|reason=How could a tax damage welfare? Don't taxes fund welfare? Maybe re-word to increase clarity.|date=February 2021}}
The term ''laissez-faire'' is often used interchangeably with the term "[[free market]]." Some may use the term ''laissez-faire'' to refer to "let do, let pass" attitude for concepts in areas outside of economics.<ref>As well as being used in economic management, the term has also been applied more broadly to a style of [[management]] and [[leadership]], where it typically describes any form of control where the controlled are given most or all of the decision-making power. In this limited usage, ''laissez-faire'' (imperative) has come to be distinct from ''laisser faire'' (infinitive), which refers to a careless attitude in the application of a policy, implying a lack of consideration or thought.</ref>


Proponents of ''laissez-faire'' argue for a near complete separation of government from the economic sector.<ref>Quick Reference Handbook Set, Basic Knowledge and Modern Technology (revised) by [[Edward H. Litchfield]], PhD</ref>{{verify source|date=November 2019}} The phrase ''laissez-faire'' is part of a larger French phrase and literally translates to "let [it/them] do", but in this context the phrase usually means to "let it be" and in expression "laid back".<ref>[http://www.businessdictionary.com/definition/laissez-faire.html "Laissez-faire"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150927104045/http://www.businessdictionary.com/definition/laissez-faire.html |date=2015-09-27 }}, ''Business Dictionary''.</ref> Although never practiced with full consistency, ''laissez-faire'' [[capitalism]] emerged in the mid-18th century and was further popularized by [[Adam Smith]]'s book ''[[The Wealth of Nations]]''.<ref>[[Edward H. Litchfield]]. "Quick Reference Handbook Set, Basic Knowledge and Modern Technology" (revised ed.).</ref><ref>{{cite web |title=Adam Smith |url=https://www.britannica.com/biography/Adam-Smith/The-Wealth-of-Nations |website=[[Encyclopædia Britannica]] |access-date=12 April 2020 |archive-date=12 April 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200412082514/https://www.britannica.com/biography/Adam-Smith/The-Wealth-of-Nations |url-status=live }}</ref>
Laissez-faire is associated with [[classical liberalism]], [[libertarianism]], and [[objectivism (Ayn Rand)|objectivism]].{{cn}}<!--"associated with" is too weak as it can include anything.--> It was originally introduced in the English-language world in 1774, by [[George Whatley]], in the book 'Principles of Trade', which was co-authored with [[Benjamin Franklin]]. Classical economists, such as [[Thomas Malthus]], [[Adam Smith]] and [[David Ricardo]] did not use the term—[[Jeremy Bentham|Bentham]] did, but only with the advent of the [[Anti-Corn Law League]] did the term receive much of its (English) meaning.<ref>{{cite journal|author=Abbott P. Usher et al.|title=Economic History--The Decline of Laissez Faire|year=1931|journal=American Economic Review|volume=22|issue=1, Supplement|pages=3-10}}</ref>


== Economic theory ==
== Etymology and usage ==
The term ''laissez-faire'' likely originated in a meeting that took place around 1681 between powerful French [[List of Finance Ministers of France|Controller-General of Finances]] [[Jean-Baptiste Colbert]] and a group of French businessmen headed by M. Le Gendre. When the eager [[Mercantilism|mercantilist]] minister asked how the French state could be of service to the merchants and help promote their commerce, Le Gendre replied simply: "Laissez-nous faire" ("Leave it to us" or "Let us do [it]", the French verb not requiring an [[Object (grammar)|object]]).<ref>[http://commons.wikimedia.org/w/index.php?title=File%3AJournal_oeconomique_-_janvier_1751.djvu "Journal Oeconomique"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200430073342/https://commons.wikimedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:Journal_oeconomique_-_janvier_1751.djvu |date=2020-04-30 }}. 1751 article by the French minister of finance.</ref>
The ''laissez-faire'' means (big black man in cuba.)school of economic thought holds a pure or [[Economic liberalism|economically liberal]] market view: that the [[free market]] is best left to its own devices, and that it will dispense with inefficiencies in a more deliberate and quick manner than any legislating body could. The basic idea is that less government interference in private economic decisions such as pricing, production, consumption, and distribution of goods and services makes for a better (more efficient) economy.


The anecdote on the Colbert–Le Gendre meeting appeared in a 1751 article in the ''Journal économique'', written by French minister and champion of [[free trade]] [[René Louis de Voyer de Paulmy d'Argenson|René de Voyer, Marquis d'Argenson]]—also the first known appearance of the term in print.<ref>M. d'Argenson, "Lettre au sujet de la dissertation sur le commerce du marquis de Belloni', Avril 1751, ''Journal Oeconomique'' [https://books.google.com/books?id=k4ABAAAAYAAJ&pg=RA3-PA111 p. 111] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221026125133/https://books.google.com/books?id=k4ABAAAAYAAJ&pg=RA3-PA111 |date=2022-10-26 }}. See A. Oncken, ''Die Maxime Laissez faire et laissez passer, ihr Ursprung, ihr Werden'', 1866</ref> Argenson himself had used the phrase earlier (1736) in his own diaries in a famous outburst:
Economist [[Adam Smith]] in his book '[[Wealth of Nations]]' argued that the ''[[invisible hand]]'' of the market would guide people to act in the public interest by following their own self-interest, since the only way to make money would be through voluntary exchange, and thus the only way to get the people's money was to ''give the people what they want.''
{{blockquote|Laissez faire, telle devrait être la devise de toute puissance publique, depuis que le monde est civilisé [...]. Détestable principe que celui de ne vouloir grandir que par l'abaissement de nos voisins ! Il n'y a que la méchanceté et la malignité du cœur de satisfaites dans ce principe, et l'intérêt y est opposé. Laissez faire, morbleu ! Laissez faire !!<ref>As quoted in J. M. Keynes, 1926, "The End of Laissez Faire". Argenson's ''Mémoirs'' were published only in 1858, ed. Jannet, Tome V, p. 362. See A. Oncken (''Die Maxime Laissez faire et laissez passer, ihr Ursprung, ihr Werden'', 1866).</ref><br /><br />Let go, which should be the motto of all public power, since the world was civilized [...]. [It is] a detestable principle of those that want to enlarge [themselves] but by the abasement of our neighbours. There is but the wicked and the malignant heart[s] [who are] satisfied by this principle and [its] interest is opposed. Let go, for God's sake! Let go!!<ref>Original somewhat literal translation using the [https://fr.wiktionary.org/wiki/laissez-faire#fr French Wiktionary] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190605064658/https://fr.wiktionary.org/wiki/laissez-faire#fr |date=2019-06-05 }}.</ref>|sign=René Louis de Voyer de Paulmy d'Argenson}}
One does not get one's dinner by appealing to the brother-love of the butcher, the farmer or the baker. Rather one appeals to their self interest, and pays them for their labour.{{cn}}


[[Vincent de Gournay]], a French [[Physiocracy|Physiocrat]] and intendant of commerce in the 1750s, popularized the term ''laissez-faire'' as he allegedly adopted it from [[François Quesnay]]'s writings on China.<ref>{{cite book|last=Baghdiantz McCabe|first=Ina|title=Orientalism in Early Modern France: Eurasian Trade Exoticism and the Ancien Regime|year=2008|publisher=Berg Publishers|isbn=978-1-84520-374-0|pages=271–272}}</ref> Quesnay coined the phrases ''laissez-faire'' and ''laissez-passer'',<ref>{{cite web|title=Encyclopædia Britannica|date=31 May 2023|url=https://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/487095/Francois-Quesnay|publisher=Encyclopædia Britannica, Inc.|access-date=23 June 2022|archive-date=22 May 2015|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150522121904/http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/487095/Francois-Quesnay|url-status=live}}</ref> ''laissez-faire'' being a translation of the Chinese term ''[[wu wei]]'' (無為).<ref name=Clarke>{{cite book|last=Clarke|first=J. J.|title=Oriental Enlightenment: The Encounter Between Asian and Western Thought|year=1997|publisher=Routledge|isbn=978-0-415-13376-0|page=50}}</ref> Gournay ardently supported the removal of restrictions on trade and the deregulation of industry in France. Delighted with the Colbert–Le Gendre anecdote,<ref>According to J. [[Anne-Robert-Jacques Turgot, Baron de Laune|Turgot]]'s "Eloge de Vincent de Gournay," '' Mercure'', August, 1759 (repr. in ''Oeuvres of Turgot'', vol. 1 [https://books.google.com/books?id=5KQALAckPr8C&pg=PA288 p. 288] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221112154804/https://books.google.com/books?id=5KQALAckPr8C&pg=PA288 |date=2022-11-12 }}.</ref> he forged it into a larger maxim all his own: "Laissez faire et laissez passer" ("Let do and let pass"). His motto has also been identified as the longer "Laissez faire et laissez passer, le monde va de lui même !" ("Let do and let pass, the world goes on by itself!"). Although Gournay left no written tracts on his economic policy ideas, he had immense personal influence on his contemporaries, notably his fellow Physiocrats, who credit both the ''laissez-faire'' slogan and the doctrine to Gournay.<ref>Gournay was credited with the phrase by [[Jacques Turgot]] ("Eloge a Gournay", ''Mercure'' 1759), the [[Victor de Riqueti, marquis de Mirabeau|Marquis de Mirabeau]] (''Philosophie rurale'' 1763 and ''Ephémérides du Citoyen'', 1767.), the Comte d'Albon ("Éloge Historique de M. Quesnay", ''Nouvelles Ephémérides Économiques'', May, 1775, pp. 136–137) and [[Pierre Samuel du Pont de Nemours|DuPont de Nemours]] (Introduction to ''Oeuvres de Jacques Turgot'', 1808–11, Vol. I, pp. 257, 259, Daire ed.) among others.</ref>
==History of Laissez-faire==
===Europe===
In 19th century Britain, laissez-faire found a small but strong following by such [[Manchester Liberalism|Manchester Liberals]] as [[Richard Cobden]] and [[Richard Wright]]. In 1867, this resulted in a free trade treaty being signed between Britain and France, after which several of these treaties were signed among other European countries. The newspaper ''[[The Economist]]'' was founded earlier in 1843, and [[free trade]] was discussed in such places as ''The Cobden Club'', founded a year after the death of Richard Cobden, in 1866.<ref>{{cite journal|author=Scott Gordon|title=The London Economist and the High Tide of Laissez Faire|year=1955|journal=Journal of Political Economy|volume=63|issue=6|pages=461-488}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|title=London Clubs in the Late Nineteenth Century|url=http://www.nuff.ox.ac.uk/economics/history/paper28/28taddeiweb1.pdf|author=Antonia Taddei|year=1999}}</ref>


Before d'Argenson or Gournay, [[Pierre Le Pesant, sieur de Boisguilbert|P. S. de Boisguilbert]] had enunciated the phrase "On laisse faire la nature" ("Let nature run its course").<ref>"Tant, encore une fois, qu'on laisse faire la nature, on ne doit rien craindre de pareil", P.S. de Boisguilbert, 1707, ''Dissertation de la nature des richesses, de l'argent et des tributs''.</ref> D'Argenson himself during his life was better known for the similar, but less-celebrated motto "Pas trop gouverner" ("Govern not too much").<ref>DuPont de Nemours, ''op cit'', p. 258. Oncken (''op.cit'') and Keynes (''op.cit''.) also credit the Marquis d'Argenson with the phrase "''Pour gouverner mieux, il faudrait gouverner moins''" ("To govern best, one needs to govern less"), possibly the source of the famous "That government is best which governs least" motto popular in American circles, attributed variously to [[Thomas Paine]], [[Thomas Jefferson]] and [[Henry Thoreau]].</ref>
However, laissez-faire was never the main doctrine of any nation, and the end of the eighteen-hundreds, European countries would find themselves taking up economic protectionism and interventionism again. France for example, started cancelling its free trade agreements with other European countries in 1890. Germany's [[protectionism]] started (again) with a December 1878 letter from [[Bismarck]], resulting in the iron and rye [[tariff]] of 1879.


The Physiocrats proclaimed ''laissez-faire'' in 18th-century France, placing it at the very core of their economic principles and famous economists, beginning with [[Adam Smith]], developed the idea.<ref name="Fine, Sidney 1964">Fine, Sidney. ''Laissez Faire and the General-Welfare State''. United States: The University of Michigan Press, 1964. Print</ref> It is with the Physiocrats and the classical [[political economy]] that the term ''laissez-faire'' is ordinarily associated.<ref>Macgregor, ''Economic Thought and Policy'' (London, 1949), pp. 54–67</ref> The book ''Laissez Faire and the General-Welfare State'' states: "The physiocrats, reacting against the excessive mercantilist regulations of the France of their day, expressed a belief in a 'natural order' or liberty under which individuals in following their selfish interests contributed to the general good. Since, in their view, this natural order functioned successfully without the aid of government, they advised the state to restrict itself to upholding the rights of private property and individual liberty, to removing all artificial barriers to trade, and to abolishing all useless laws."<ref name="Fine, Sidney 1964"/>
===North America===
In the United States, laissez-faire was mainly present up to the [[American Civil War]], although various protectionist measures were passed by the North against the South before that time (e.g. the [[tariff of 1828]]). The more abide protectionist influences came from [[Henry Clay]] and his ''[[American System (economic plan)|American System]]''.{{cn}}


The French phrase ''laissez-faire'' gained currency in English-speaking countries with the spread of Physiocratic literature in the late 18th century. [[George Whatley]]'s 1774 ''Principles of Trade'' (co-authored with [[Benjamin Franklin]]) re-told the Colbert-LeGendre anecdote; this may mark the first appearance of the phrase in an English-language publication.<ref>Whatley's ''Principles of Trade'' are reprinted in ''Works of Benjamin Franklin, Vol.2'', [https://books.google.com/books?id=C2QUAAAAYAAJ&pg=PA401 p. 401] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221112154809/https://books.google.com/books?id=C2QUAAAAYAAJ&pg=PA401 |date=2022-11-12 }}.</ref>
===The Great Depression===
{{POV-sect}}
{{main|Causes of the Great Depression}}
Economists and historians (such as [[John Maynard Keynes]]) argue that laissez-faire economic policy fostered the conditions under which the Great Depression arose. In Keynes' 1936 work, ''The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money'', Keynes introduced important concepts that were intended to help explain the Great Depression. The argument for a laissez-faire economic policy during a recession was that if consumption fell, then the rate of interest would fall. Lower interest rates would lead to increased investment spending and demand would remain constant. However, Keynes points out that there are good reasons why investment does not necessarily automatically increase as a response to a fall in consumption. Businesses make investments based on expectations of profit. Therefore, if a fall in consumption appears to be long-term, businesses analyzing trends will lower expectations of futures sales. Therefore, the last thing they are interested in doing is investing in increasing future production, even if lower interest rates make capital inexpensive. In that case, contrary to Say’s law, the economy can be thrown into a general slump. ((Keen 2000:198)) This self-reinforcing dynamic is what happened to an extreme degree during the Depression, where bankruptcies were common and investment, which requires a degree of optimism, was very unlikely to occur.


[[Herbert Spencer]] was opposed to a slightly different application of ''laissez faire''—to "that miserable ''laissez-faire''" that leads to men's ruin, saying: "Along with that miserable ''laissez-faire'' which calmly looks on while men ruin themselves in trying to enforce by law their equitable claims, there goes activity in supplying them, at other men's cost, with gratis novel-reading!"<ref>''Justice Part IV of Ethics'' (1892). p. 44.</ref>
Keyne's believed that classical liberal economics had a fatal flaw, and that was market instability as a result of inadequate investment. In Keynes’s view, since private actors cannot be counted on to create aggregate demand during a recession, the government has the responsibility to create demand.<ref> Yergin, Daniel., and Joseph Stanislaw. 1998. The Commanding Heights. Touchstone Book. p 21-22</ref>


As a product of the [[Age of Enlightenment|Enlightenment]], ''laissez-faire'' was "conceived as the way to unleash human potential through the restoration of a natural system, a system unhindered by the restrictions of government".<ref name="Gaspard, Toufick 2004">Gaspard, Toufick. ''A Political Economy of Lebanon 1948–2002: The Limits of Laissez-faire''. Boston: Brill, 2004. {{ISBN|978-90-04-13259-7}}{{page needed|date=March 2022}}</ref> In a similar vein, Adam Smith{{When|date=December 2016}} viewed the economy as a natural system and the market as an organic part of that system. Smith saw ''laissez-faire'' as a moral program and the market its instrument to ensure men the rights of [[natural law]].<ref name="Gaspard, Toufick 2004"/> By extension, [[free market]]s become a reflection of the natural system of liberty.<ref name="Gaspard, Toufick 2004"/> For Smith, ''laissez-faire'' was "a program for the abolition of laws constraining the market, a program for the restoration of order and for the activation of potential growth".<ref name="Gaspard, Toufick 2004"/>
[[Friedrich August von Hayek]] and [[Milton Friedman]], in contrast, argued that the Great Depression was not a result of laissez-faire economic policy but a result of too much government intervention and regulation upon the market. They note that the Great Depression was the longest depression in U.S. history and the only depression in which the government heavily intervened. In Friedman's work, ''Capitalism and Freedom'' he argues: "A governmentally established agency--The Federal Reserve System--had been assigned responsibility for monetary policy. In 1930 and 1931, it exercised this responsibility so ineptly as to convert what otherwise would have been a moderate contraction into a major catastrophe."<ref>Friedman, Milton. 1962. ''Capitalism and Freedom.'' University of Chicago Press. p 38.</ref>


However, Smith<ref name=asoae/> and notable [[Classical economics|classical economists]] such as [[Thomas Malthus]] and [[David Ricardo]] did not use the phrase. [[Jeremy Bentham]] used the term, but it was probably{{original research inline|date=December 2016}} [[James Mill]]'s reference to the ''laissez-faire'' maxim (together with the "Pas trop gouverner" motto) in an 1824 entry for the ''Encyclopædia Britannica'' that really brought the term into wider English usage. With the advent of the [[Anti-Corn Law League]] (founded 1838), the term received much of its English meaning.<ref>{{cite journal|author=Abbott P. Usher|title=Economic History – The Decline of Laissez Faire|year=1931|journal=American Economic Review|volume=22|issue=1, supplement|pages=3–10|display-authors=etal}}</ref>{{request quotation|date=July 2017}}
Furthermore, the U.S. Federal government had created a fixed currency pegged to the value of gold. At one point the pegged value was considerably higher than the world price which created a massive surplus of gold. Demand for gold surged and the world price increased but the pegged value was too low in the U.S. and this created a massive migration of gold from the U.S.{{cn}} Friedman and Hayek both believed that this inability to react to currency demand created a run on the banks that the banks were no longer able to handle, and that and the fixed exchange rates between the dollar and gold both worked to cause the Great Depression by creating, and then not fixing, deflationary pressures.<ref>ibid, 45-50</ref> He further argued in this thesis, that the government inflicted more pain upon the American public by first raising taxes, then by printing money to pay debts (thus causing inflation), the combination of which helped to wipe out the savings of the middle class. Friedman concludes that the effects of the Great Depression were not mitigated until after World War II when the economy saw a return to normalcy with the elimination of many price controls. This opinion specifically blames a combination of [[Federal Reserve]] policies and economic regulation by the U.S. government as causes of the Great Depression, and that the depression was exacerbated by raising income taxes on the highest incomes from 25% to 63%, a "check tax", and the [[Smoot-Hawley tariff]]. Friedman believed that [[Herbert Hoover]]'s interventionist policies and [[Franklin Delano Roosevelt|Franklin Roosevelt's]] [[New Deal]] further lengthened and worsened the depression. Friedman concludes, "The Great Depression in the United States, far from being a sign of the inherent instability of the private enterprise system, is a testament to how much harm can be done by mistakes on the part of a few men when they wield vast power over the monetary system of a country."<ref>ibid, 50</ref>


Smith first used the metaphor of an [[invisible hand]] in his book ''[[The Theory of Moral Sentiments]]'' (1759) to describe the unintentional effects of economic self-organization from economic self-interest.<ref>Andres Marroquin, ''Invisible Hand: The Wealth of Adam Smith'', The Minerva Group, Inc., 2002, {{ISBN|1-4102-0288-7}}, p. 123.</ref> Although not the metaphor itself, the idea lying behind the invisible hand belongs to [[Bernard Mandeville|Bernard de Mandeville]] and his ''[[Fable of the Bees]]'' (1705). In political economy, that idea and the doctrine of ''laissez-faire'' have long been closely related.<ref>John Eatwell, ''The Invisible Hand'', W. W. Norton & Company, 1989, pp. Preface, x1.</ref> Some have characterized the invisible-hand metaphor as one for ''laissez-faire'',<ref>{{cite book|url=https://archive.org/details/mathematicalcent0000odif|title=The mathematical century: the 30 greatest problems of the last 100 years (2006) Piergiorgio Odifreddi, Arturo Sangalli, Freeman J Dyson, p. 122|access-date=30 July 2013|isbn=978-0-691-12805-4|publisher=Princeton University Press|date=22 October 2006|url-access=registration}}</ref> although Smith never actually used the term himself.<ref name=asoae>Roy C. Smith, ''Adam Smith and the Origins of American Enterprise: How the Founding Fathers Turned to a Great Economist's Writings and Created the American Economy'', Macmillan, 2004, {{ISBN|0-312-32576-2}}, pp. 13–14.</ref> In ''Third Millennium Capitalism'' (2000), Wyatt M. Rogers Jr. notes a trend whereby recently "conservative politicians and economists have chosen the term 'free-market capitalism' in lieu of ''laissez-faire''".<ref>{{cite book|last1=Rogers|first1=Wyatt M.|chapter=1: Economic Forces in Modern Capitalism|title=Third Millennium Capitalism: Convergence of Economic, Energy, and Environmental Forces|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=7adF9D3OJ0EC|series=ABC-Clio ebook|location=Westport, Connecticut|publisher=Greenwood Publishing Group|date=2000|page=38|isbn=978-1-56720-360-8|access-date=30 December 2016}}</ref>
=== Return of market economies after the Second World War===
{{main|Neoliberalism|Ordoliberalism|Social market economy|Reaganomics|Thatcherism}}
After the Second World War, laissez-faire thinking was in part resurrected through the [[Austrian School]] and [[Chicago School (economics)|Chicago School]], and such liberal thinkers as [[Ludwig von Mises]], [[Friedrich Hayek]] and [[Milton Friedman]], who argued that if the [[Free World]] was truly defined by its freedom, then its citizens should have full economic freedom. [[Hong Kong]] was the first territory to embrace laissez-faire economic policy in this era, having officially followed that path since the [[1960s]].


American [[individualist anarchists]] such as [[Benjamin Tucker]] saw themselves as economic ''laissez-faire'' socialists and political individualists while arguing that their "anarchistic socialism" or "individual anarchism" was "consistent [[Manchesterism]]".<ref>Tucker, Benjamin (1926). ''Individual Liberty: Selections from the Writings of Benjamin R. Tucker''. New York: Vanguard Press. pp. 1–19.{{ISBN?}}</ref>
[[Germany]] implemented, with broad coalition support between the Christian Democratic and Social Democratic parties, what is called the [[Social market economy]], which restored Germany's war-devastated economy by letting prices float freely. Later in the [[1970s]] and [[1980s]], the ideas of the Chicago School found "resonance" in Pinochet's economic policies in [[Chile]], Ronald Reagan's [[Reaganomics]], and in the privatization policies of [[Thatcher]].{{cn}}


== History ==
The return of market economies after the Second World War is still a far cry from laissez-faire proper. The United States, in the 1980s, for example, sought to protect its automobile industry by "voluntary" export restrictions from Japan.<ref>{{cite journal|author=Robert W. Crandall|year=1987|title=The Effects of U.S. Trade Protection for Autos and Steel|journal=Brookings Papers on Economic Activity|volume=1987|issue=1|pages=271-288}}</ref> One scholar wrote about the early 1980s that:{{cquote|By and large, the comparative strength of the dollar against major foreign currencies has reflected high U.S. interest rates driven by huge federal budget deficits. Hence, the source of much of the current deterioration of trade is not the general state of the economy, but rather the government's mix of fiscal and monetary policies — that is, the problematic juxtaposition of bold tax reductions, relatively tight monetary targets, generous military outlays, and only modest cuts in major entitlement programs. Put simply, the roots of the trade problem and of the resurgent protectionism it has fomented are fundamentally political as well as economic.<ref>{{cite journal|author=Pietro S. Nivola|year=1986|title=The New Protectionism: U.S. Trade Policy in Historical Perspective|journal=[[Political Science Quarterly]]|volume=101|issue=4|pages=577-600}}</ref>}}
=== Europe ===
{{main|Economic liberalism}}
{{see also|Classical liberalism}}
In Europe, the ''laissez-faire'' movement was first widely promoted by the [[Physiocracy|Physiocrats]], a movement that included [[Vincent de Gournay]] (1712–1759), a successful merchant turned political figure. Gournay is postulated to have adapted the Taoist concept ''[[wu wei]]'',<ref>[[Christian Gerlach]], [http://hsozkult.geschichte.hu-berlin.de/daten/2005/gerlach_christian_wu-wei.pdf Wu-Wei in Europe. A Study of Eurasian Economic Thought] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200803052148/http://hsozkult.geschichte.hu-berlin.de/daten/2005/gerlach_christian_wu-wei.pdf |date=2020-08-03 }}, London School of Economics – March 2005 p. 3" the diffusion of ''wu-wei'', co-evolved with the inner-European ''laissez-faire'' principle, the Libaniusian model." p. 8 "Thus, ''wu-wei'' has to be recognized as a ''laissez-faire'' instrument of Chinese political economy "p. 10 "Practising ''wu-wei erzhi''. Consequently, it is this variant of the ''laissez-faire'' maxim in which the basis of Physiocracy's 'moral philosophy' is to be located. Priddat's work made clear that the ''wu-wei'' of the complete ''économie'' has to be considered central to Physiocracy; "p. 11 "that ''wu-wei'' translates into French as ''laissez-faire''".</ref> from the writings on China by [[François Quesnay]]<ref name=Clarke/> (1694–1774). Gournay held that government should allow the [[Natural law|laws of nature]] to govern economic activity, with the state only intervening to protect life, liberty and property. [[François Quesnay]] and [[Anne Robert Jacques Turgot]], Baron de l'Aulne took up Gournay's ideas. Quesnay had the ear of the King of France, [[Louis XV of France|Louis XV]] and in 1754 persuaded him to give ''laissez-faire'' a try. On September 17, the King abolished all tolls and restraints on the sale and transport of grain. For more than a decade, the experiment appeared successful, but 1768 saw a poor harvest, and the cost of bread rose so high that there was widespread starvation while merchants exported grain to obtain the best profit. In 1770, the [[List of Finance Ministers of France|Comptroller-General of Finances]] [[Joseph Marie Terray]] revoked the edict allowing free trade in grain.<ref>Will & Ariel Durant, ''Rousseau and the Revolution'', pp. 71–77, Simon and Schuster, 1967, {{ISBN|0-671-63058-X}}.</ref>


The doctrine of ''laissez-faire'' became an integral part of [[Classical liberalism|19th-century European liberalism]].<ref name="Fine, Sidney 1964"/> Just as liberals supported [[freedom of thought]] in the intellectual sphere, so were they equally prepared to champion the principles of [[free trade]] and [[free competition]] in the sphere of economics, seeing the state as merely a [[Night-watchman state|passive policeman]], protecting [[private property]] and administering justice, but not interfering with the affairs of its citizens. Businessmen, British industrialists in particular, were quick to associate these principles with their own economic interests.<ref name="Fine, Sidney 1964"/> Many of the ideas of the physiocrats spread throughout Europe and were adopted to a greater or lesser extent in Sweden, Tuscany, Spain and in the newly created United States. [[Adam Smith]], author of ''[[The Wealth of Nations]]'' (1776), met Quesnay and acknowledged his influence.<ref>Will & Ariel Durant, ''Rousseau and the Revolution'', p. 76, Simon and Schuster, 1967, {{ISBN|0-671-63058-X}}.</ref>
==Laissez-faire today==
Most modern industrialized nations today are not representative of laissez-faire principles or policies, as they usually involve significant amounts of [[government]] intervention in the economy. This intervention includes [[minimum wages]], [[corporate welfare]], [[antitrust|anti-trust regulation]], [[nationalization|nationalized industries]], [[social welfare|welfare programs]] as a way to provide a safety net for those without the capacity to find work or work because of disability, [[subsidy]] programs for businesses and agricultural products, [[government ownership]] of some industry (usually in natural resources), [[regulation]] of market competition, and economic [[trade]] barriers in the form of protective tariffs - quotas on imports - or internal regulation favoring domestic industry, and other forms of government favoritism. However, there are some economies regarded to be based on laissez-faire. The most often-cited is Hong Kong's [[positive non-interventionism]]. The policy was first officially laid down by [[Sir Charles Haddon Cave]] who was the Financial Secretary of Hong Kong from 1971-1981. Hong Kong is ranked number one for 12 consecutive years in the [[Index of Economic Freedom]] which attempts to measure "the absence of government coercion or constraint on the production, distribution, or consumption of goods and services beyond the extent necessary for citizens to protect and maintain liberty itself." [[Milton Friedman]] praised the Hong Kong Laissez-faire approach to the economy and credits that policy for the rapid move from poverty to prosperity in 50 years. [http://www.hooverdigest.org/983/friedman.html] Much of this growth came under British colonial control prior to the 1997 takeover by Communist China.


In Britain, the newspaper ''[[The Economist]]'' (founded in 1843) became an influential voice for ''laissez-faire'' [[capitalism]].<ref>{{cite journal|author=Scott Gordon|title=The London Economist and the High Tide of Laissez Faire|year=1955|journal=Journal of Political Economy|volume=63|issue=6|pages=461–488|doi=10.1086/257722|s2cid=154921783}}</ref> ''Laissez-faire'' advocates opposed food aid for famines occurring within the [[British Empire]]. In 1847, referring to the famine then underway in Ireland, founder of ''The Economist'' [[James Wilson (businessman)|James Wilson]] wrote: "It is no man's business to provide for another".<ref>{{cite book|author=Cormac Ó Gráda|title=The Great Irish Famine|year=1995|chapter=section: ''Ideology and relief'' in Chpt. 2|isbn=978-0-521-55787-0|publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]]|author-link=Cormac Ó Gráda}}</ref> More specifically, in [[An Essay on the Principle of Population]], [[Malthus]] argued that there was nothing that could be done to avoid famines because he felt he had mathematically proven that population growth tends to exceed growth in food production. However, ''The Economist'' campaigned against the [[Corn Laws]] that protected landlords in the [[United Kingdom of Great Britain and Ireland]] against competition from less expensive foreign imports of cereal products. The [[Great Famine (Ireland)|Great Famine]] in Ireland in 1845 led to the repeal of the Corn Laws in 1846. The tariffs on grain which kept the price of bread artificially high were repealed.<ref>George Miller. ''On Fairness and Efficiency''. The Policy Press, 2000. {{ISBN|978-1-86134-221-8}} p. 344</ref> However, repeal of the Corn Laws came too late to stop the Irish famine, partly because it was done in stages over three years.<ref>Christine Kinealy. ''A Death-Dealing Famine:The Great Hunger in Ireland''. Pluto Press, 1997. {{ISBN|978-0-7453-1074-9}}. p. 59.</ref>
However at a press conference on 11 September 2006, [[Donald Tsang]], the Chief Executive of Hong Kong said that "Positive non-interventionism was a policy suggested by a previous Financial Secretary many years ago, but we have never said that we would still use it as our current policy... We prefer the so-called 'big market, small government' policy." Responses in Hong Kong were widely divided, some see it as an announcement to abandon the positive non-interventionism, others see it as a more realistic response to the government policies in the past few years, such as the building of Disney, the intervention of the stock market to prevent brokering. (Ref: 2006-Sept-12: Mingpao Daily).


A group that became known as the [[Manchester capitalism|Manchester Liberals]], to which [[Richard Cobden]] (1804–1865) and [[John Bright]] (1811–1889) belonged, were staunch defenders of free trade. After the death of Cobden, the [[Cobden Club]] (founded in 1866) continued their work.<ref>{{cite web|title=London Clubs in the Late Nineteenth Century|url=http://www.nuff.ox.ac.uk/economics/history/paper28/28taddeiweb1.pdf|author=Antonia Taddei|year=1999|access-date=30 December 2008|archive-date=17 December 2008|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081217115036/http://www.nuff.ox.ac.uk/economics/history/paper28/28taddeiweb1.pdf|url-status=live}}</ref> The breakdown of ''laissez-faire'' as practised by the British Empire was partly led by British companies eager for state support of their positions abroad, in particular British oil companies.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Jones|first=G. Gareth|year=1977|title=The British Government and the Oil Companies 1912–1924: The Search for an Oil Policy|journal=[[The Historical Journal]]|volume=2 |issue=3|pages=647–672|jstor=2638433|doi=10.1017/s0018246x00011286|s2cid=161977401 }}</ref>
==References==
<!--See http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Wikipedia:Footnotes for an explanation of how to generate footnotes using the <ref(erences/)> tags-->
<references/>
* {{cite journal|author=Brebner, John Bartlet|year=1948|title=Laissez Faire and State Intervention in Nineteenth-Century Britain|journal=Journal of Economic History|volume=8|pages=59-73}}
* {{cite journal|author=[[Irving Fisher|Fisher, Irving]]|year=1907|month=January|title=Why has the Doctrine of Laissez Faire been Abandoned?|journal=[[Science (journal)|Science]]|volume=25|issue=627| pages=18-27}}
* {{cite journal|author=[[Frank William Taussig|Taussig, Frank W.]]|year=1904|title=The Present Position of the Doctrine of Free Trade|journal=[[American Economic Association|Publications of the American Economic Association]]|volume=6|issue=1|pages=29-65}}


{{Anchor|Liberismo}}
==Further reading==
In Italy, philosopher [[Benedetto Croce]] created the term "liberism" (derived from the Italian term ''liberismo''), a term for the [[economic doctrine]] of ''laissez-faire'' [[capitalism]]; it is synonymous with [[economic liberalism]]. He claimed that "Liberalism can prove only a temporary right of private propriety of land and industries."<ref>(Croce-Einaudi, 1988, p. 139)</ref> It was popularized in English by Italian political scientist [[Giovanni Sartori]].<ref>Giovanni Sartori. ''The Theory of Democracy Revisited'' (1987). [[Chatham, New Jersey]]. Chatham House. {{ISBN|0-934540-49-7}}.</ref> Sartori specifically imported the term from Italian to distinguish between [[social liberalism]], which is generally considered a [[political ideology]] often advocating extensive government intervention in the economy, and those [[economic liberal]] theories that propose to virtually eliminate such intervention. In informal usage, liberism overlaps with other concepts such as [[free trade]], [[neoliberalism]], [[right-libertarianism]], the American concept of [[Libertarianism in the United States|libertarianism]],<ref name=":2" /> and the ''laissez-faire'' doctrine of the French liberal [[Doctrinaires]]. The intention of Croce and of Sartori to attack the right to private property and to free enterprise separating them from the general philosophy of liberalism, that is primarily a theory of natural rights, was always criticised openly by the quoted philosophers and by some of the main representatives of liberalism, such as [[Luigi Einaudi]], [[Friedrich Hayek]],<ref name=":2">{{cite news|author=Pietro Moroni|url=https://www.pandorarivista.it/articoli/le-due-facce-della-medaglia-neoliberale/|title=Le due facce della medaglia neoliberale – Pandora Rivista|work=Pandora Rivista|date=25 April 2015|access-date=22 October 2018|archive-date=22 June 2018|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180622032453/https://www.pandorarivista.it/articoli/le-due-facce-della-medaglia-neoliberale/|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{Treccani|croce-ed-einaudi-un-confronto-su-liberalismo-e-liberismo_(Croce-e-Gentile)/|Croce ed Einaudi: un confronto su liberalismo e liberismo|accesso=22 ottobre 2018|autore=Marcello Montanari|anno=2016}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |title=Liberalismo politico e liberalismo economico|author=Dario Antiseri|publisher=Rubettino}}</ref> and [[Milton Friedman]].<ref>{{cite book |title=Liberalismo|author=F.Hayek|publisher=Ideazione|page=62|year=1997|quote=Ciò comporta anche il rifiuto della distinzione tra liberalismo politico e liberalismo economico /elaborata in particolare da Croce come distinzione tra liberismo e liberalismo) Per la tradizione inglese, i due concetti sono inseparabili. Infatti, il principio fondamentale per cui l'intervento coercitivo dell'autorità statale deve limitarsi ad imporre il rispetto delle norme generali di mera condotta priva il governo del potere di dirigere e controllare le attività economiche degli individui.}}</ref> The [[Austrian School]] economist [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]] argues that the differences between the economical concept of liberism<ref>I sostenitori dell'esistenza di una dottrina liberista la attribuiscono ad [[Adam Smith]] e al suo saggio ''La Ricchezza delle Nazioni'', laddove questi utilizzò il termine "liberal policy" un paio di volte per indicare il commercio privo di dazi. Smith non vedeva di buon occhio l'assenza di regolamentazione statale, infatti dichiarò: «''Raramente la gente dello stesso mestiere si ritrova insieme, anche se per motivi di svago e di divertimento, senza che la conversazione risulti in una cospirazione contro i profani o in un qualche espediente per far alzare i prezzi''»''.''</ref> and the economical consequences of liberalism<ref>La lingua francese parla di ''libéralisme politique'' e ''libéralisme économique'' (quest'ultimo chiamato anche ''laissez-faire'', lett. ''lasciate fare''), lo spagnolo di ''liberalismo social'' e ''liberalismo económico''. La lingua inglese parla di ''free trade'' (libero commercio) ma usa il termine ''liberalism'' anche per riferirsi al liberismo economico.</ref><ref>{{Cite web|url=http://www.fondazioneluigieinaudi.it/Download/lezione_Scognamiglio_2011.pdf|title=Liberismo e liberalismo nella polemica fra Croce ed Einaudi|first=Scogniamiglio Pasini|last=Carlo|access-date=22 October 2018|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161228124608/http://www.fondazioneluigieinaudi.it/Download/lezione_Scognamiglio_2011.pdf|archive-date=28 December 2016}}</ref> can be summarized by saying that "A market is a law system. Without it, the only possible economy is the street robbery."<ref>{{cite book |title=Potere o legge economica?|last=Boehm-Bawerk|publisher=Rubbettino|page=67|year=1999}}</ref>
*{{cite book | author = Oncken, August | year = 1886 | title = Die Maxime Laissez faire et laissez passer : ihr Ursprung, ihr Werden. Ein Beitrag zur Geschichte der Freihandelslehre | publisher = K.J. Wyss | location = Bern }}


=== United States ===
==Comparative economic systems==
{{main|Liberalism in the United States}}
* [[American School (economics)|American School]]
Frank Bourgin's study of the [[Constitutional Convention (United States)|Constitutional Convention]] and subsequent decades argues that direct government involvement in the economy was intended by the [[Founding Fathers of the United States|Founding Fathers]].<ref name=bourgin>{{cite book|first=Frank|last=Bourgin|title=The Great Challenge: The Myth of Laissez-Faire in the Early Republic|isbn=978-0-06-097296-7|year=1989|publisher=George Braziller Inc.|location=New York}}{{page needed|date=March 2022}}</ref> The reason for this was the economic and financial chaos the nation suffered under the [[Articles of Confederation]]. The goal was to ensure that dearly-won political independence was not lost by being economically and financially dependent on the powers and princes of Europe. The creation of a strong central government able to promote science, invention, industry and commerce was seen as an essential means of [[Taxing and Spending Clause|promoting the general welfare]] and making the [[economy of the United States]] strong enough for them to determine their own destiny. Others view Bourgin's study, written in the 1940s and not published until 1989, as an over-interpretation of the evidence, intended originally to defend the New Deal and later to counter [[Ronald Reagan]]'s economic policies.<ref>{{cite web|last=Bourgin|first=Frank|url=https://www.kirkusreviews.com/book-reviews/frank-bourgin/the-great-challenge-the-myth-of-laissez-faire-i/|title=The Great Challenge: The Myth of Laissez-faire in the Early Republic|publisher=Kirkusreviews.com|date=1 June 1989|access-date=30 July 2013|archive-date=21 September 2013|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130921055716/https://www.kirkusreviews.com/book-reviews/frank-bourgin/the-great-challenge-the-myth-of-laissez-faire-i/|url-status=live}}</ref>
* [[Collectivism#Economics|Collectivism]]
* [[Communism]]
* [[Corporatism]]
* [[Dirigisme]]
* [[Japanese post-war economic miracle|Japanese Economic Miracle]]
* [[Market socialism]]
* [[Mixed economy]]
* [[Planned economy]]
* [[Socialism]]
* [[Social market economy|Social Market Economy]]
* [[Third way]]


Historian Kathleen G. Donohue argues that in the 19th century [[liberalism in the United States]] had distinctive characteristics and that "at the center of classical liberal theory [in Europe] was the idea of ''laissez-faire''. To the vast majority of American classical liberals, however, ''laissez-faire'' did not mean "no government intervention" at all. On the contrary, they were more than willing to see government provide tariffs, railroad subsidies, and internal improvements, all of which benefited producers". Notable examples of government intervention in the period prior to the [[American Civil War]] include the establishment of the [[United States Patent and Trademark Office|Patent Office]] in 1802; the establishment of the Office of Standard Weights and Measures in 1830; the creation of the Survey of the Coast (later renamed the United States Coast Survey and then the [[United States Coast and Geodetic Survey]]) in 1807 and other measures to improve river and harbor navigation; the various [[United States Army|Army]] expeditions to the west, beginning with [[Lewis and Clark Expedition|Lewis and Clark]]'s [[Corps of Discovery]] in 1804 and continuing into the 1870s, almost always under the direction of an officer from the Army [[Corps of Topographical Engineers]] and which provided crucial information for the overland pioneers that followed; the assignment of Army Engineer officers to assist or direct the surveying and construction of the early railroads and canals; and the establishment of the [[First Bank of the United States]] and [[Second Bank of the United States]] as well as various protectionist measures (e.g. the [[Tariff of Abominations|tariff of 1828]]). Several of these proposals met with serious opposition and required a great deal of horse-trading to be enacted into law. For instance, the First National Bank would not have reached the desk of President [[George Washington]] in the absence of an agreement that was reached between [[Alexander Hamilton]] and several Southern members of Congress to locate the capitol in the [[District of Columbia]]. In contrast to Hamilton and the [[Federalist Party|Federalists]] was [[Thomas Jefferson]] and [[James Madison]]'s opposing political party, the [[Democratic-Republican Party|Democratic-Republicans]].
==See also==

Most of the early opponents of ''laissez-faire'' capitalism in the United States subscribed to the [[American School (economics)|American School]]. This school of thought was inspired by the ideas of Hamilton, who proposed the creation of a [[First Bank of the United States|government-sponsored bank]] and increased tariffs to favor Northern industrial interests. Following Hamilton's death, the more abiding [[Protectionism|protectionist]] influence in the antebellum period came from [[Henry Clay]] and his [[American System (economic plan)|American System]]. In the early 19th century, "it is quite clear that the ''laissez-faire'' label is an inappropriate one" to apply to the relationship between the United States government and industry.<ref name="Prince Taylor">{{cite journal|last1=Prince|first1=Carl E.|last2=Taylor|first2=Seth|year=1982|title=Daniel Webster, the Boston Associates, and the U.S. Government's Role in the Industrializing Process, 1815–1830|journal=Journal of the Early Republic|volume=2|issue=3|pages=283–299|jstor=3122975|doi=10.2307/3122975 }}</ref> In the mid-19th century, the United States followed the [[Whig Party (United States)|Whig]] tradition of [[economic nationalism]], which included increased state control, regulation and [[Macroeconomics|macroeconomic]] development of infrastructure.<ref name=guelzo>{{cite book|first=Allen C.|last=Guelzo|title=Abraham Lincoln: Redeemer President|isbn=978-0-8028-3872-8|year=1999|url=https://archive.org/details/abrahamlincolnre00guel|publisher=W.B. Eerdmans Pub. Co|location=Grand Rapids}}{{page needed|date=March 2022}}</ref> [[Public works]] such as the provision and regulation transportation such as railroads took effect. The [[Pacific Railway Acts]] provided the development of the [[First transcontinental railroad]].<ref name="guelzo"/><ref>{{Cite web|date=2019-05-10|title=From Sea to Shining Sea: The Heroes and Villains of the First Transcontinental Railroad|url=https://theobjectivestandard.com/2019/05/from-sea-to-shining-sea-the-heroes-and-villains-of-the-first-transcontinental-railroad/|access-date=2021-04-29|website=The Objective Standard|language=en-US|archive-date=2021-04-29|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210429210027/https://theobjectivestandard.com/2019/05/from-sea-to-shining-sea-the-heroes-and-villains-of-the-first-transcontinental-railroad/|url-status=live}}</ref> To help pay for its war effort in the Civil War, the [[Federal government of the United States|United States government]] imposed its first personal [[income tax]] on 5 August 1861 as part of the [[Revenue Act of 1861]] (3% of all incomes over US$800; rescinded in 1872).

Following the Civil War, the movement towards a [[mixed economy]] accelerated. Protectionism increased with the [[McKinley Tariff]] of 1890 and the [[Dingley Tariff]] of 1897. [[Government regulation]] of the economy expanded with the enactment of the [[Interstate Commerce Act of 1887]] and the [[Sherman Anti-trust Act]]. The [[Progressive Era]] saw the enactment of more controls on the economy as evidenced by the [[Woodrow Wilson]] administration's [[The New Freedom|New Freedom]] program. Following [[World War I]] and the [[Great Depression]], the United States turned to a mixed economy which combined [[free enterprise]] with a [[Progressive tax|progressive income tax]] and in which from time to time the government stepped in to support and protect American industry from competition from overseas. For example, in the 1980s the government sought to protect the automobile industry by "voluntary" export restrictions from Japan.<ref>{{cite journal|author=Robert W. Crandall|year=1987|title=The Effects of U.S. Trade Protection for Autos and Steel|journal=Brookings Papers on Economic Activity|volume=1987|issue=1|pages=271–288|doi=10.2307/2534518|jstor=2534518|url=https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/1987/01/1987a_bpea_crandall.pdf|access-date=2019-09-24|archive-date=2019-10-01|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191001135513/https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/1987/01/1987a_bpea_crandall.pdf|url-status=live}}</ref>

In 1986, Pietro S. Nivola wrote: "By and large, the comparative strength of the dollar against major foreign currencies has reflected high U.S. interest rates driven by huge federal budget deficits. Hence, the source of much of the current deterioration of trade is not the general state of the economy, but rather the government's mix of fiscal and monetary policies – that is, the problematic juxtaposition of bold tax reductions, relatively tight monetary targets, generous military outlays, and only modest cuts in major entitlement programs. Put simply, the roots of the trade problem and of the resurgent protectionism it has fomented are fundamentally political as well as economic".<ref>{{cite journal|author=Pietro S. Nivola|year=1986|title=The New Protectionism: U.S. Trade Policy in Historical Perspective|journal=[[Political Science Quarterly]]|volume=101|issue=4|pages=577–600|doi=10.2307/2150795|jstor=2150795}}</ref>

A more recent advocate of total ''laissez-faire'' has been [[Objectivism|Objectivist]] [[Ayn Rand]], who described it as "the abolition of any and all forms of government intervention in production and trade, the separation of State and Economics, in the same way and for the same reasons as the separation of Church and State".<ref>Rand, Ayn ''Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal,'' Ch. 7, New American Library, Signet, 1967.</ref> This viewpoint is summed up in what is known as the iron law of regulation, which is a theory stating that all government economic regulation eventually leads to a net loss in social welfare.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Armstrong|first1=J. Scott|last2=Green|first2=Kesten C.|date=2013-10-01|title=Effects of corporate social responsibility and irresponsibility policies|journal=Journal of Business Research|series=Strategic Thinking in Marketing|volume=66|issue=10|pages=1922–1927|doi=10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.02.014|citeseerx=10.1.1.663.508|s2cid=145059055}}</ref> Rand's political philosophy emphasized [[individual rights]] (including [[Private property|property rights]])<ref>{{harvnb|Peikoff|1991|pp=350–352}}.</ref> and she considered ''laissez-faire'' capitalism the only moral social system because in her view it was the only system based on the protection of those rights.<ref name="rights">{{harvnb|Gotthelf|2000|pp=91–92}}; {{harvnb|Peikoff|1991|pp=379–380}}.</ref> She opposed [[statism]], which she understood to include [[theocracy]], [[absolute monarchy]], [[Nazism]], [[fascism]], [[communism]], [[socialism]] and dictatorship.<ref>{{harvnb|Peikoff|1991|pp=369}}.</ref> Rand believed that natural rights should be enforced by a constitutionally limited government.<ref>{{harvnb|Peikoff|1991|p=367}}.</ref> Although her political views are often classified as [[Conservatism in the United States|conservative]] or [[Libertarianism in the United States|libertarian]], she preferred the term "radical for capitalism". She worked with conservatives on political projects, but disagreed with them over issues such as religion and ethics.<ref>{{harvnb|Burns|2009|pp=174–177, 209, 230–231}}; {{harvnb|Den Uyl|Rasmussen|1986|pp=225–226}}; {{harvnb|Doherty|2007|pp=189–190}}; {{harvnb|Branden|1986|p=252}}.</ref> She denounced [[libertarianism]], which she associated with [[anarchism]].<ref>{{harvnb|Sciabarra|1995|pp=266–267}}; {{harvnb|Burns|2009|pp=268–269}}.</ref> She rejected anarchism as a naïve theory based in [[subjectivism]] that could only lead to collectivism in practice.<ref>{{harvnb|Sciabarra|1995|pp=280–281}}; {{harvnb|Peikoff|1991|pp=371–372}}; {{harvnb|Merrill|1991|p=139}}.</ref>

== Models ==
=== Capitalism ===
{{main|Capitalism}}
{{see also|Neoliberalism}}
A closely related name for ''laissez-faire'' capitalism is that of raw, pure, or unrestrained capitalism, which refers to capitalism free of any regulations,<ref name="capfree">{{cite book|last1=Nolan|first1=Peter|title=Capitalism and Freedom: The Contradictory Character of Globalisation|publisher=Anthem Press|isbn=978-1-84331-282-6|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=bQdQDJzOkBMC&pg=PA3|access-date=9 February 2017|year=2008}}</ref> with low or minimal<ref>{{cite book|last1=Orchard|first1=Lionel|last2=Stretton|first2=Hugh|title=Public Goods, Public Enterprise, Public Choice: Theoretical Foundations of the Contemporary Attack on Government|publisher=Springer|isbn=978-1-349-23505-6|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=rwW_DAAAQBAJ&pg=PA230|access-date=9 February 2017|year=2016}}</ref> government and operating almost entirely on the [[profit motive]]. It shares a similar economic conception with [[anarcho-capitalism]].

Advocates of laissez-faire capitalism argue that it relies on a constitutionally limited government that unconditionally bans the initiation of force and coercion, including fraud. Therefore, free market economists such as Milton Friedman and [[Thomas Sowell]] argue that, under such a system, relationships between companies and workers are purely voluntary and mistreated workers will seek better treatment elsewhere. Thus, most companies will compete for workers on the basis of pay, benefits, and work-life balance just as they compete with one another in the marketplace on the basis of the relative cost and quality of their goods.<ref>{{Citation|title=Milton Friedman on Labor Unions – Free To Choose|url=https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=Tefm8wxCQdg |archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/varchive/youtube/20211211/Tefm8wxCQdg| archive-date=2021-12-11 |url-status=live|language=en|access-date=2021-04-29}}{{cbignore}}</ref>{{primary source inline|date=January 2022}}<ref>{{Cite web|date=2013-06-11|title=Economics vs. 'Need', by Dr. Thomas Sowell|url=https://www.creators.com/read/thomas-sowell/06/13/economics-vs-need|access-date=2021-04-29|website=www.creators.com|language=en|archive-date=2021-04-29|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210429210027/https://www.creators.com/read/thomas-sowell/06/13/economics-vs-need|url-status=live}}</ref>{{primary source inline|date=January 2022}}

So-called "raw" or "hyper-capitalism" is a major [[motif (narrative)|motif]] of [[cyberpunk]] in dystopian works such as ''[[Syndicate (series)|Syndicate]]''.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Paris|first1=Jeffrey|title=Rethinking the End of Modernity|journal=Social Philosophy Today|date=1 July 2005|volume=21|pages=173–189|doi=10.5840/socphiltoday20052120}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|last1=Kilgore|first1=Christopher D.|title=Bad Networks: From Virus to Cancer in Post-Cyberpunk Narrative|journal=Journal of Modern Literature|date=2017|volume=40|issue=2|pages=165–183|doi=10.2979/jmodelite.40.2.10|jstor=10.2979/jmodelite.40.2.10|s2cid=157670471}}</ref>

=== Socialism ===
{{main|Socialism}}
{{see also|Free-market anarchism|Market socialism|Socialist economics}}
Although ''laissez-faire'' has been commonly associated with [[capitalism]], there is a similar ''laissez-faire'' economic theory and system associated with socialism called left-wing ''laissez-faire'',<ref>Nick Manley. [http://c4ss.org/content/27009 "Brief Introduction To Left-Wing Laissez Faire Economic Theory: Part One"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210818131348/http://c4ss.org/content/27009 |date=2021-08-18 }}.</ref><ref>Nick Maley. [https://c4ss.org/content/27062 "Brief Introduction To Left-Wing Laissez Faire Economic Theory: Part Two".] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210516192528/https://c4ss.org/content/27062 |date=2021-05-16 }}</ref> or [[free-market anarchism]], also known as [[Left-wing market anarchism|free-market anti-capitalism]] and [[Market socialism|free-market socialism]] to distinguish it from ''laissez-faire'' capitalism.<ref>Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). ''Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty''. Brooklyn, NY:Minor Compositions/Autonomedia</ref><ref>"It introduces an eye-opening approach to radical social thought, rooted equally in libertarian socialism and market anarchism." Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). ''Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty''. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia. p. back cover.</ref><ref>"But there has always been a market-oriented strand of libertarian socialism that emphasizes voluntary cooperation between producers. And markets, properly understood, have always been about cooperation. As a commenter at Reason magazine's Hit&Run blog, remarking on [[Jesse Walker]]'s link to the Kelly article, put it: "every trade is a cooperative act." In fact, it's a fairly common observation among market anarchists that genuinely free markets have the most legitimate claim to the label "socialism."" [http://c4ss.org/content/670 "Socialism: A Perfectly Good Word Rehabilitated"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160310111716/https://c4ss.org/content/670 |date=2016-03-10 }} by [[Kevin Carson]] at website of Center for a Stateless Society.</ref> One first example of this is [[Mutualism (economic theory)|mutualism]] as developed by [[Pierre-Joseph Proudhon]] in the 18th century, from which emerged [[individualist anarchism]]. [[Benjamin Tucker]] is one eminent [[American individualist anarchist]] who adopted a ''laissez-faire'' system he termed [[anarchistic socialism]] in contraposition to [[state socialism]].<ref>Tucker, Benjamin. [http://fair-use.org/benjamin-tucker/instead-of-a-book/state-socialism-and-anarchism#art1p1 "State Socialism and Anarchism"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190311065032/http://fair-use.org/benjamin-tucker/instead-of-a-book/state-socialism-and-anarchism#art1p1 |date=2019-03-11 }}.</ref><ref>Brown, Susan Love. 1997. "The Free Market as Salvation from Government". In ''Meanings of the Market: The Free Market in Western Culture''. Berg Publishers. p. 107.</ref> This tradition has been recently associated with contemporary scholars such as [[Kevin Carson]],<ref>Carson, Kevin A. (2008). ''Organization Theory: A Libertarian Perspective''. Charleston, SC:BookSurge.</ref><ref>Carson, Kevin A. (2010). ''The Homebrew Industrial Revolution: A Low-Overhead Manifesto''. Charleston, SC: BookSurge.</ref> Roderick T. Long,<ref>Long, Roderick T. (2000). ''Reason and Value: Aristotle versus Rand''. Washington, DC:Objectivist Center</ref><ref>Long, Roderick T. (2008). "[http://en.liberalis.pl/2008/01/04/interview-with-roderick-long/ An Interview With Roderick Long] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200327050439/https://en.liberalis.pl/2008/01/04/interview-with-roderick-long/ |date=2020-03-27 }}"</ref> Charles W. Johnson,<ref>Johnson, Charles W. (2008). "[http://radgeek.com/gt/2010/03/02/liberty-equality-solidarity-toward-a-dialectical-anarchism/ Liberty, Equality, Solidarity: Toward a Dialectical Anarchism] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220626123451/https://radgeek.com/gt/2010/03/02/liberty-equality-solidarity-toward-a-dialectical-anarchism/ |date=2022-06-26 }}." ''Anarchism/Minarchism: Is a Government Part of a Free Country?'' In Long, Roderick T. and Machan, Tibor Aldershot: Ashgate pp. 155–188.</ref> Brad Spangler,<ref>Spangler, Brad (15 September 2006). "[http://bradspangler.com/blog/archives/473 Market Anarchism as Stigmergic Socialism] {{webarchive|url=https://archive.today/20110510102306/http://bradspangler.com/blog/archives/473|date=10 May 2011}}.</ref> Sheldon Richman,<ref>Richman, Sheldon (23 June 2010). "[http://sheldonfreeassociation.blogspot.com/2006/07/why-left-libertarian.html Why Left-Libertarian?] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200103113718/http://sheldonfreeassociation.blogspot.com/2006/07/why-left-libertarian.html |date=2020-01-03 }}" ''The Freeman''. Foundation for Economic Education.</ref><ref>Richman, Sheldon (18 December 2009). "[http://www.thefreemanonline.org/columns/tgif/workers-of-the-world-unite Workers of the World Unite for a Free Market"]. {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140722145233/http://www.thefreemanonline.org/columns/tgif/workers-of-the-world-unite|date=22 July 2014}}." Foundation for Economic Education.</ref><ref name="LibertarianLeft">Sheldon Richman (3 February 2011). "[http://www.theamericanconservative.com/blog/libertarian-left/ Libertarian Left: Free-market anti-capitalism, the unknown ideal] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120509201621/http://www.theamericanconservative.com/blog/libertarian-left/|date=9 May 2012}}." ''The American Conservative''. Retrieved 5 March 2012.</ref> [[Chris Matthew Sciabarra]]<ref>Sciabarra, Chris Matthew (2000). ''Total Freedom: Toward a Dialectical Libertarianism''. University Park, PA:Pennsylvania State University Press.</ref> and [[Gary Chartier]],<ref>Chartier, Gary (2009). ''Economic Justice and Natural Law''. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.</ref> who stress the value of radically free markets, termed [[freed market]]s to distinguish them from the common conception which these [[left-libertarians]] believe to be riddled with [[capitalist]] and [[statist]] privileges.<ref name="marketsnotcap">Gillis, William (2011). "The Freed Market." In Chartier, Gary and Johnson, Charles. ''Markets Not Capitalism''. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia. pp. 19–20.</ref> Referred to as left-wing market anarchists<ref>Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). ''Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty''. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia. pp. 1–16.</ref> or market-oriented left-libertarians,<ref name="LibertarianLeft"/> proponents of this approach strongly affirm the [[classical liberal]] ideas of [[self-ownership]] and [[free market]]s while maintaining that taken to their logical conclusions these ideas support [[anti-capitalist]], [[anti-corporatist]], [[Social hierarchies|anti-hierarchical]] and [[pro-labor]] positions in economics; [[anti-imperialism]] in foreign policy; and thoroughly radical views regarding such cultural issues as gender, sexuality and race.<ref>Gary Chartier and Charles W. Johnson (eds). ''Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty''. Minor Compositions; 1st edition (November 5, 2011</ref><ref>Gary Chartier has joined Kevin Carson, Charles W. Johnson and others (echoing the language of [[Benjamin Tucker]], [[Lysander Spooner]] and [[Thomas Hodgskin]]) in maintaining that—because of its heritage, emancipatory goals and potential—radical market anarchism should be seen by its proponents and by others as part of the socialist tradition and that market anarchists can and should call themselves socialists. See Gary Chartier, "Advocates of Freed Markets Should Oppose Capitalism," "Free-Market Anti-Capitalism?" session, annual conference, [[Association of Private Enterprise Education]] (Cæsar's Palace, Las Vegas, NV, April 13, 2010); Gary Chartier, [http://c4ss.org/content/1738 "Advocates of Freed Markets Should Embrace 'Anti-Capitalism'"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190929195335/http://c4ss.org/content/1738 |date=2019-09-29 }}; Gary Chartier, [http://invisiblemolotov.wordpress.com/2009/09/12/socialist-ends-market-means/ ''Socialist Ends, Market Means: Five Essays''] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190328044107/https://c4ss.org/content/1738 |date=2019-03-28 }} . Cp. Tucker, "Socialism."</ref> Critics of ''laissez-faire'' as commonly understood argues that a truly ''laissez-faire'' system would be anti-capitalist and socialist.<ref>Nick Manley, [http://c4ss.org/content/27009 "Brief Introduction To Left-Wing Laissez Faire Economic Theory: Part One"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210818131348/http://c4ss.org/content/27009 |date=2021-08-18 }}.</ref><ref>Nick Manley, [https://c4ss.org/content/27062 "Brief Introduction To Left-Wing Laissez Faire Economic Theory: Part Two"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210516192528/https://c4ss.org/content/27062 |date=2021-05-16 }}.</ref>

Kevin Carson describes his politics as on "the outer fringes of both free market [[libertarianism]] and [[socialism]]"<ref>[https://c4ss.org/content/11792 "Introductions – Kevin Carson"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190329172601/http://c4ss.org/content/11792 |date=2019-03-29 }}.</ref> and has also been highly critical of intellectual property.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://c4ss.org/content/521|title=Intellectual Property – A Libertarian Critique|publisher=c4ss.org|access-date=May 23, 2009|last=Carson|first=Kevin|archive-date=September 11, 2012|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120911011138/http://c4ss.org/content/521|url-status=live}}</ref> Carson has identified the work of Benjamin Tucker, [[Thomas Hodgskin]], [[Ralph Borsodi]], [[Paul Goodman (writer)|Paul Goodman]], [[Lewis Mumford]], [[Elinor Ostrom]], [[Peter Kropotkin]] and [[Ivan Illich]] as sources of inspiration for his approach to politics and economics.<ref>Kevin A. Carson, [http://c4ss.org/content/11792 Introduction] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121016061056/http://c4ss.org/content/11792 |date=2012-10-16 }}, ''The Art of the Possible''.</ref> In addition to individualist anarchist Benjamin Tucker's big four monopolies (land, money, tariffs and patents), he argues that the [[Sovereign state|state]] has also transferred wealth to the wealthy by subsidizing organizational centralization in the form of transportation and communication subsidies. Carson believes that Tucker overlooked this issue due to Tucker's focus on individual market transactions whereas he also focuses on organizational issues. As such, the primary focus of his most recent work has been decentralized manufacturing and the informal and household economies.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://c4ss.org/content/78|title=Industrial Policy: New Wine in Old Bottles|publisher=c4ss.org|access-date=May 26, 2009|last=Carson|first=Kevin|archive-date=September 11, 2012|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120911011215/http://c4ss.org/content/78|url-status=live}}</ref> The theoretical sections of Carson's ''[[Studies in Mutualist Political Economy]]'' are also presented as an attempt to integrate [[marginalist]] critiques into the [[labor theory of value]].<ref>Kevin Carson, [http://www.mutualist.org/id112.html "Studies in Mutualist Political Economy"], {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110415135834/http://www.mutualist.org/id112.html|date=15 April 2011}} chs. 1–3.</ref>

In response to claims that he uses the term capitalism incorrectly, Carson says he is deliberately choosing to resurrect what he claims to be an old definition of the term to "make a point". He claims that "the term 'capitalism,' as it was originally used, did not refer to a free market, but to a type of statist class system in which capitalists controlled the state and the state intervened in the market on their behalf".<ref>Carson, Kevin A. [https://www.mises.org/journals/jls/20_1/20_1_7.pdf Carson's Rejoinders] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140817054508/http://mises.org/journals/jls/20_1/20_1_7.pdf |date=2014-08-17 }}. Journal of Libertarian Studies, Volume 20, No. 1 (Winter 2006): 97–136 [116–117].</ref> Carson holds that "capitalism, arising as a new class society directly from the old class society of the [[Middle Ages]], was founded on an act of robbery as massive as the earlier [[Feudalism|feudal]] conquest of the land. It has been sustained to the present by continual state intervention to protect its system of privilege without which its survival is unimaginable".<ref name="Richman">Richman, Sheldon, [http://www.amconmag.com/blog/libertarian-left/ Libertarian Left] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110814153531/http://www.amconmag.com/blog/libertarian-left/|date=14 August 2011}}, ''[[The American Conservative]]'' (March 2011).</ref> Carson argues that in a truly ''laissez-faire'' system the ability to extract a profit from labor and capital would be negligible.<ref>{{cite journal|url=http://www.anxietyculture.com/bluffecon.htm#zerointerest|title=Bluffer's Guide to Revolutionary Economics|first=Brian|last=Dean|journal=[[The Idler (1993)|The Idler]]|date=Winter 2002|access-date=24 May 2009|archive-date=27 April 2009|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090427124422/http://www.anxietyculture.com/bluffecon.htm#zerointerest|url-status=live}}</ref> Carson coined the [[pejorative]] term vulgar libertarianism, a phrase that describes the use of a free market rhetoric in defense of [[corporate capitalism]] and [[economic inequality]]. According to Carson, the term is derived from the phrase vulgar political economy which [[Karl Marx]] described as an economic order that "deliberately becomes increasingly apologetic and makes strenuous attempts to talk out of existence the ideas which contain the contradictions [existing in economic life]".<ref>Marx, ''Theories of Surplus Value, III,'' p. 501.</ref>

Gary Chartier offers an understanding of [[property rights]] as contingent yet tightly constrained social strategies, reflective of the importance of multiple, overlapping rationales for separate [[ownership]] and of [[natural law]] principles of practical reasonableness, defending robust yet non-absolute protections for these rights in a manner similar to that employed by [[David Hume]].<ref>See Gary Chartier, ''Anarchy and Legal Order: Law and Politics for a Stateless Society'' (New York: Cambridge UP 2013) 44–156.</ref> This account is distinguished both from [[Lockean]] and neo-Lockean views which deduce property rights from the idea of self-ownership and from [[consequentialist]] accounts that might license widespread ad hoc interference with the possessions of groups and individuals.<ref>See Gary Chartier, "Natural Law and Non-Aggression," ''Acta Juridica Hungarica'' 51.2 (June 2010): 79–96 and, for an earlier version, ''Justice'' 32–46.</ref> Chartier uses this account to ground a clear statement of the natural law basis for the view that solidaristic wealth [[redistribution (economics)|redistribution]] by individual persons is often morally required, but as a response by individuals and grass-roots networks to particular circumstances rather than as a state-driven attempt to achieve a particular distributive pattern.<ref>See ''Justice'' 47–68.</ref> He advances detailed arguments for [[workplace democracy]] rooted in such natural law principles as [[subsidiarity]],<ref>''Justice'' 89–120.</ref> defending it as morally desirable and as a likely outcome of the elimination of injustice rather than as something to be mandated by the state.<ref>See Gary Chartier, "Pirate Constitutions and Workplace Democracy," ''Jahrbuch für Recht und Ethik'' 18 (2010): 449–467.</ref>

Chartier has discussed natural law approaches to [[land reform]] and to the [[occupation of factories]] by workers.<ref>''Justice'' 123–154.</ref> He objects on natural law grounds to intellectual property protections, drawing on his theory of property rights more generally<ref>See Gary Chartier,' "Intellectual Property and Natural Law," ''Australian Journal of Legal Philosophy'' 36 (2011): 58–88.</ref> and develops a general natural law account of [[boycotts]].<ref>See ''Justice'' 176–182.</ref> He has argued that proponents of genuinely freed markets should explicitly reject capitalism and identify with the global anti-capitalist movement while emphasizing that the abuses the anti-capitalist movement highlights result from state-tolerated violence and state-secured privilege rather than from voluntary cooperation and exchange. According to Chartier, "it makes sense for [freed-market advocates] to name what they oppose 'capitalism.' Doing so calls attention to the freedom movement's radical roots, emphasizes the value of understanding society as an alternative to the state, underscores the fact that proponents of freedom object to non-aggressive as well as aggressive restraints on liberty, ensures that advocates of freedom aren't confused with people who use market rhetoric to prop up an unjust status quo, and expresses solidarity between defenders of freed markets and workers — as well as ordinary people around the world who use "capitalism" as a short-hand label for the world-system that constrains their freedom and stunts their lives".<ref name="Richman"/><ref>[https://c4ss.org/content/1738 "Advocates of Freed Markets Should Embrace "Anti-Capitalism"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211023155347/http://c4ss.org/content/1738 |date=2021-10-23 }}.</ref>

== Criticism ==

{{further|Criticism of capitalism}}
Over the years, a number of economists have offered critiques of ''laissez-faire'' economics. [[Adam Smith]] acknowledges some moral ambiguities towards the system of capitalism.<ref name="Spencer J. Pack 2010">Spencer J. Pack. Capitalism as a Moral System: Adam Smith's Critique of the Free Market Economy. Great Britain: Edward Elgar, 2010. Print</ref> Smith had misgivings concerning some aspects of each of the major character-types produced by modern capitalist society, namely the landlords, the workers and the capitalists.<ref name="Spencer J. Pack 2010"/> Smith claimed that "[t]he landlords' role in the economic process is passive. Their ability to reap a revenue solely from ownership of [[land (economics)|land]] tends to make them indolent and inept, and so they tend to be unable to even look after their own economic interests"<ref name="Spencer J. Pack 2010"/> and that "[t]he increase in population should increase the demand for food, which should increase rents, which should be economically beneficial to the landlords". According to Smith, the landlords should be in favour of policies which contribute to the growth in the wealth of nations, but they often are not in favour of these pro-growth policies because of their own indolent-induced ignorance and intellectual flabbiness.<ref name="Spencer J. Pack 2010"/> Smith stated clearly that he believed that without morality and laws, society would fail. From that perspective, it seems dubious that Smith supported a pure Laissez-Faire style of capitalism, and the ideas he supports in ''[[The Wealth of Nations]]'' is heavily dependent on the moral philosophy from his previous work, ''Theory of Moral Sentiment''.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Macfie|first=A.L.|date=1959|title=Adam Smith's Moral Sentiments as Foundation for His Wealth of Nations|journal=Oxford Economic Papers|volume=11|issue=3|pages=209–228|doi=10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a040824}}</ref>

Many philosophers have written on the systems society has created to manage their civilizations. [[Thomas Hobbes]] used the concept of a "[[State of nature#Thomas Hobbes|state of nature]]", which is a time before any government or laws, as a starting point to consider the question. In this time, life would be "[[war of all against all]]". Further, "In such condition, there is no place for industry; because the fruit thereof is uncertain&nbsp;... continual fear and danger of violent death, and the life of man solitary, poor, nasty, brutish, and short."<ref>{{Cite book|last=Hobbes|first=Thomas|title=Of Man, Being the First Part of Leviathan|publisher=Collier & Son|year=1909–14}}</ref>

Regardless of preferred political preference, all societies require shared moral values as a prerequisite on which to build laws to protect individuals from each other. Adam Smith wrote Wealth of Nations during the Enlightenment, a period of time when the prevailing attitude was, "All things can be Known." In effect, European thinkers, inspired by the likes of Isaac Newton and others, set about to "find the laws" of all things, that there existed a "natural law" underlying all aspects of life. They believed that these could be discovered and that everything in the universe could be rationally demystified and catalogued, including human interactions.<ref>{{cite web|date=2009|title=Enlightenment|url=https://www.history.com/topics/british-history/enlightenment|access-date=2021-04-29|website=History.com|archive-date=2021-02-07|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210207161303/https://www.history.com/topics/british-history/enlightenment|url-status=live}}</ref>

Critics and [[Market abolitionism|market abolitionists]] such as [[David McNally (professor)|David McNally]] argue in the Marxist tradition that the logic of the market inherently produces inequitable outcomes and leads to unequal exchanges, arguing that Smith's moral intent and moral philosophy espousing equal exchange was undermined by the practice of the free market he championed. According to McNally, the development of the [[market economy]] involved coercion, exploitation and violence that Smith's moral philosophy could not countenance.<ref>{{cite book|last=McNally|first=David|title=Against the Market: Political Economy, Market Socialism and the Marxist Critique|publisher=Verso|year=1993|isbn=978-0-86091-606-2}}</ref>

The British economist [[John Maynard Keynes]] condemned ''laissez-faire'' economic policy on several occasions.<ref>Dostaler, Gilles, ''Keynes and His Battles'' (Edward Elgar Publishing, 2007), p. 91.</ref> In ''The End of Laissez-faire'' (1926), one of the most famous of his critiques, Keynes argues that the doctrines of ''laissez-faire'' are dependent to some extent on improper deductive reasoning and says the question of whether a market solution or state intervention is better must be determined on a case-by-case basis.<ref>Dostaler 2007, p. 91; Barnett, Vincent, ''John Maynard Keynes'' (Routledge, 2013), p. 143.</ref>

The [[Austrian School]] economist [[Friedrich Hayek]] stated that a freely competitive, ''laissez-faire'' banking industry tends to be endogenously destabilizing and pro-cyclical, arguing that the need for [[central banking]] control was inescapable.<ref>{{cite journal|last=White|first=Lawrence H.|title=Why Didn't Hayek Favor Laissez Faire in Banking?|journal=History of Political Economy|year=1999|volume=31|issue=4|url=http://cameroneconomics.com/white-hayek-hope.pdf|access-date=11 April 2013|doi=10.1215/00182702-31-4-753|pages=753–769|archive-date=1 April 2013|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130401121918/http://cameroneconomics.com/white-hayek-hope.pdf|url-status=live}}</ref>

[[Karl Polanyi]]'s ''[[The Great Transformation (book)|Great Transformation]]'' criticizes self-regulating markets as aberrational, unnatural phenomena which tend towards social disruption.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Polanyi|first=Karl|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=IfeMAAAAIAAJ|title=The Great Transformation|date=1944|publisher=Farrar & Rinehart|language=en}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|last=McCloskey|first=Deirdre|date=1997|title=Polanyi Was Right, and Wrong|url=https://www.deirdremccloskey.com/docs/pdf/Article_303.pdf|journal=Eastern Economic Journal|access-date=2021-07-26|archive-date=2021-08-07|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210807221706/https://www.deirdremccloskey.com/docs/pdf/Article_303.pdf|url-status=live}}</ref>

In modern economics laissez-faire typically has a bad connotation, which hints towards a perceived need for restraint due to social needs and securities that can not be adequately responded to by companies with just a motive for making profit.

[[Robert Kuttner]] states that "for over a century, popular struggles in democracies have used the [[nation-state]] to temper raw capitalism. The power of voters has offset the power of capital. But as national barriers have come down in the name of freer commerce, so has the capacity of governments to manage capitalism in a broad public interest. So the real issue is not 'trade' but democratic governance".<ref>{{cite web |last1=Kuttner |first1=Robert |date=19 December 2001 |title=Globalization and Its Critics |url=https://prospect.org/article/globalization-and-its-critics |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180913002631/http://prospect.org/article/globalization-and-its-critics |archive-date=13 September 2018 |access-date=17 March 2019 |publisher=The American Prospect}}</ref>

The main issues of raw capitalism are said to lie in its disregard for quality, [[durability]], [[sustainability]], respect for the [[Environmental protection|environment]] and human beings as well as a lack of [[morality]].<ref>{{cite book |last1=Kerckhove |first1=Gilbert Van |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=POefWmtaZcgC&pg=PA17 |title=Toxic Capitalism: The Orgy of Consumerism and Waste: Are We the Last Generation on Earth? |publisher=AuthorHouse |year=2012 |isbn=978-1-4772-1906-5 |language=en |access-date=9 February 2017}}</ref> From this more critical angle, companies might naturally aim to maximise profits at the expense of workers' and broader social interests.<ref>{{cite web |title=Müntefering's criticism of raw capitalism strikes a chord |url=http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/6af06832-bdda-11d9-87aa-00000e2511c8.html |url-access=subscription |url-status=live |archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/archive/20221210/http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/6af06832-bdda-11d9-87aa-00000e2511c8.html |archive-date=2022-12-10 |access-date=9 February 2017 |work=Financial Times}}{{dead link|date=July 2018|bot=InternetArchiveBot|fix-attempted=yes}}</ref>

== See also ==
{{Portal|Capitalism|Economics|Law|Libertarianism}}
{{cols|colwidth=21em}}
* [[Anarcho-capitalism]]
* [[Anarcho-capitalism]]
* "Authoritarian liberalism", a term by [[Hermann Heller (legal scholar)|Hermann Heller]]
* [[Corporatocracy]]
* [[Deregulation]]
* [[Economic liberalism]]
* [[Economic liberalism]]
* [[Capitalism]]
* [[Free market]]
* [[Central planning]]
* [[Free-market anarchism]]
* [[Classical liberalism]]
* [[Free trade]]
* [[Criticisms of capitalism]]
* [[History of economic thought]]
* [[Economic Democracy]]
* [[Liberism]]
* [[Government ownership]]
* [[German model]]
* [[Liberalism]]
* [[Libertarianism]]
* [[Libertarianism]]
* [[Objectivist philosophy]]
* [[Market fundamentalism]]
* [[Ordoliberalism]]
* [[Market socialism]]
* [[Manchester capitalism]]
* [[Neoliberalism]]
* [[Objectivism]]
* [[Physiocracy]]
* [[Privatization]]
* [[Wu wei]]
{{colend}}

== References ==
{{reflist}}

==Sources==
* {{cite book |title=[[The Passion of Ayn Rand]] |last=Branden |first=Barbara |author-link=Barbara Branden |location=Garden City, New York |publisher=Doubleday & Company |year=1986 |isbn=0-385-19171-5 |oclc=12614728}}
* {{cite book|title=Goddess of the Market: Ayn Rand and the American Right |last=Burns |first=Jennifer |location=New York |publisher=[[Oxford University Press]] |year=2009 |isbn=978-0-19-532487-7 |oclc=313665028 |title-link=Goddess of the Market: Ayn Rand and the American Right}}
* {{cite book |title=The Philosophic Thought of Ayn Rand |title-link=The Philosophic Thought of Ayn Rand |editor1-last=Den Uyl |editor1-first=Douglas |editor2-last=Rasmussen |editor2-first=Douglas |location=Chicago |publisher=[[University of Illinois Press]] |year=1986 |orig-date=1984 |isbn=978-0-252-01407-9 |edition=paperback |name-list-style=amp}}
* {{cite book |title=Radicals for Capitalism: A Freewheeling History of the Modern American Libertarian Movement |last=Doherty |first=Brian |author-link=Brian Doherty (journalist) |location=New York |publisher=[[Public Affairs Press]] |year=2007 |isbn=978-1-58648-350-0 |title-link=Radicals for Capitalism: A Freewheeling History of the Modern American Libertarian Movement}}
* {{cite book|title=On Ayn Rand |last=Gotthelf |first=Allan |author-link=Allan Gotthelf |publisher=[[Wadsworth Publishing]] |year=2000 |isbn=978-0-534-57625-7 |title-link=On Ayn Rand}}
* {{cite book|title=Objectivism: The Philosophy of Ayn Rand |last=Peikoff |first=Leonard |location=New York |publisher=[[E. P. Dutton|Dutton]] |year=1991 |isbn=978-0-452-01101-4 |title-link=Objectivism: The Philosophy of Ayn Rand}}
* {{Cite book |title=The Ideas of Ayn Rand |last=Merrill |first=Ronald E. |location=La Salle, Illinois |publisher=[[Open Court Publishing Company|Open Court Publishing]] |year=1991 |isbn=0-8126-9157-1 |url=https://archive.org/details/ideasofaynrand00merr}}
* {{cite book|title=Ayn Rand: The Russian Radical |last=Sciabarra |first=Chris Matthew |author-link=Chris Matthew Sciabarra |location=University Park|publisher=Pennsylvania State University Press |year=1995 |isbn=978-0-271-01440-1 |oclc=31133644 |title-link=Ayn Rand: The Russian Radical}}

== Further reading ==
{{refbegin|40em}}
* {{cite journal |author=Brebner, John Bartlet |author-link=John Bartlet Brebner |year=1948 |title=Laissez Faire and State Intervention in Nineteenth-Century Britain |journal=Journal of Economic History |volume=8 |pages=59–73 |doi=10.1017/S0022050700090252 |s2cid=154256232}}
* {{cite journal |author=Fisher, Irving |date=January 1907 |title=Why has the Doctrine of Laissez Faire been Abandoned? |journal=[[Science (journal)|Science]] |volume=25 |issue=627 |pages=18–27 |doi=10.1126/science.25.627.18 |jstor=1633692 |pmid=17739703 |bibcode=1907Sci....25...18F |url=https://zenodo.org/record/1447976 |author-link=Irving Fisher |access-date=2020-09-02 |archive-date=2021-04-20 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210420164520/https://zenodo.org/record/1447976 |url-status=live }}
* {{cite journal |author=Taussig, Frank W. |year=1904 |title=The Present Position of the Doctrine of Free Trade |journal=[[American Economic Association|Publications of the American Economic Association]] |volume=6 |issue=1 |pages=29–65 |author-link=Frank William Taussig}}
* Gerlach, Cristian (2005) Wu-Wei in Europe: [http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/22479/ A Study of Eurasian Economic Thought] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210322161107/http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/22479/ |date=2021-03-22 }} London School of Economics.
* {{cite book |last1=Block |first1=Fred |author1-link=Fred L. Block |last2=Somers |first2=Margaret R. |year=2014 |title=The Power of Market Fundamentalism: Karl Polyani's Critique |location=Cambridge, MA |publisher=[[Harvard University Press]] |isbn=978-0-674-05071-6 |url=http://www.hup.harvard.edu/catalog.php?isbn=9780674050716 |access-date=2014-12-31 |archive-date=2021-04-29 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210429085412/https://www.hup.harvard.edu/catalog.php?isbn=9780674050716 |url-status=live }}
* Bourgin, Frank ''The Great Challenge: The Myth of Laissez-Faire in the Early Republic'' (George Braziller Inc., 1989; Harper & Row, 1990).
* {{cite encyclopedia |last=Caplan |first=Bryan |author-link=Bryan Caplan |editor-first=Ronald |editor-last=Hamowy |editor-link=Ronald Hamowy |encyclopedia=The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism |chapter-url=https://sk.sagepub.com/reference/libertarianism/n167.xml |year=2008 |publisher=[[SAGE Publishing|Sage]]; [[Cato Institute]] |location=Thousand Oaks, CA |doi=10.4135/9781412965811.n167 |isbn=978-1-4129-6580-4 |oclc=750831024 |lccn=2008009151 |pages=279–281 |chapter=Laissez-Faire Policy |access-date=2022-03-18 |archive-date=2022-03-31 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220331220937/https://sk.sagepub.com/reference/libertarianism/n167.xml |url-status=live }}
* {{cite web |url=http://hsozkult.geschichte.hu-berlin.de/daten/2005/gerlach_christian_wu-wei.pdf |title=Wu-Wei in Europe. A Study of Eurasian Economic Thought |access-date=2009-02-13 |archive-date=2020-08-03 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200803052148/http://hsozkult.geschichte.hu-berlin.de/daten/2005/gerlach_christian_wu-wei.pdf |url-status=live }} {{small|(773&nbsp;KB)}} by Christian Gerlach, London School of Economics – March 2005.
* [http://www.panarchy.org/keynes/laissezfaire.1926.html John Maynard Keynes, The end of laissez-faire (1926)] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20181027124319/http://www.panarchy.org/keynes/laissezfaire.1926.html |date=2018-10-27 }}.
* Carter Goodrich, ''[https://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=100695027 Government Promotion of American Canals and Railroads, 1800–1890] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120224210853/http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=100695027 |date=2012-02-24 }}'' (Greenwood Press, 1960).
** Goodrich, Carter. "American Development Policy: the Case of Internal Improvements," ''Journal of Economic History'', 16 (1956), 449–460. <!-- in JSTOR. -->
** Goodrich, Carter. "National Planning of Internal Improvements," ''Political Science Quarterly'', 63 (1948), 16–44. <!-- in JSTOR. -->
* Johnson, E.A.J., ''The Foundations of American Economic Freedom: Government and Enterprise in the Age of Washington'' (University of Minnesota Press, 1973).
* {{citation |title=Fabian Essays in Socialism – The Basis of Socialism – The Period of Anarchy |author=Sidney Webb |year=1889}}
* Eisenach, Eldon J. "Nation & Economy." ''The Lost Promise of Progressivism'', University Press of Kansas, 2021, pp.&nbsp;138–186, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctv1p2gkzz.10}}.
* Mittermaier, Karl, et al. "Individualism and Public Spirit." ''The Hand Behind the Invisible Hand: Dogmatic and Pragmatic Views on Free Markets and the State of Economic Theory'', 1st ed., [[Bristol University Press]], 2020, pp.&nbsp;115–148, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctv186grks.17}}.
* de Muijnck, Sam, et al. "Pragmatic Pluralism." ''Economy Studies: A Guide to Rethinking Economics Education'', [[Amsterdam University Press]], 2021, pp.&nbsp;301–327, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctv23khmgr.26}}.
* Williamson, Stephen D., and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Research Department. "Laissez-Faire Banking and Circulating Media of Exchange". no. 382, [[Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis]], pp.&nbsp;1–36, {{JSTOR|community.28111419}}.
* Schmidt, Jeremy J. "Laissez-Faire Metaphysics." ''Water: Abundance, Scarcity, and Security in the Age of Humanity'', [[New York University Press]], 2017, pp.&nbsp;43–67, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctt1ggjjbf.6}}.
* McGarity, Thomas O. "[Part One Introduction]." Freedom to Harm: The Lasting Legacy of the Laissez Faire Revival, [[Yale University Press]], 2013, pp.&nbsp;9–12, {{JSTOR|j.ctt32bhht.5}}.
* Viner, Jacob (1991). "Adam Smith and Laissee Faire". ''Essays on the Intellectual History of Economics'', edited by Douglas A. Irwin, [[Princeton University Press]], 1991, pp.&nbsp;85–113, {{JSTOR|j.ctt7ztz3w.6}}.
* McGarity, Thomas O. "The Laissez Faire Benchmark." ''Freedom to Harm: The Lasting Legacy of the Laissez Faire Revival'', [[Yale University Press]], 2013, pp.&nbsp;13–17, {{JSTOR|j.ctt32bhht.6}}.
* Colander, David and Kupers, Roland. "Laissez-Faire Activism." ''Complexity and the Art of Public Policy: Solving Society's Problems from the Bottom Up.'' [[Princeton University Press]], 2014, pp.&nbsp;214–236, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctt6wq04g.15}}.
* Bowen, Howard R., et al. "Social Responsibilities and Laissez Faire." ''Social Responsibilities of the Businessman'', [[University of Iowa Press]], 2013, pp.&nbsp;14–21, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctt20q1w8f.8}}.
* Bladen, Vincent. "Laissez Faire." ''From Adam Smith to Maynard Keynes: The Heritage of Political Economy'', [[University of Toronto Press]], 1974, pp.&nbsp;91–95, {{JSTOR|10.3138/j.ctt15jjdnk.16}}.
* Perkins, Dwight H. "Government Intervention versus Laissez-Faire in Northeast Asia." ''East Asian Development'', [[Harvard University Press]], 2013, pp.&nbsp;66–99, {{JSTOR|j.ctt6wpppr.6}}.
* Calvo, Christopher W. "Laisse-Faire in the American Tradition". ''The Emergence of Capitalism in Early America'', 1st ed., [[University Press of Florida]], 2020, pp.&nbsp;27–74, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctvwvr323.5}}.
* Stricker, Frank. "Discipline for the Unemployed; Laissez-Faire for Business (1873–1920)." ''American Unemployment: Past, Present, and Future'', [[University of Illinois Press]], 2020, pp.&nbsp;15–38, {{doi|10.5406/j.ctv1220rqn.5}}.
* Maggor, Noam. "Cultivating the Laissez-Faire Metropolis." ''Brahmin Capitalism: Frontiers of Wealth and Populism in America's First Gilded Age'', [[Harvard University Press]], 2017, pp.&nbsp;53–95, {{JSTOR|j.ctv24trd1j.6}}.
* Blaser, Mario. "Laissez-Faire Progress: Invisibilzing the Yrmo." ''Storytelling Globalization from the Chaco and Beyond'', [[Duke University Press]], 2010, pp.&nbsp;41–62, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctv11cw0jf.7}}.
* Howell, Chris. "The Construction of the Collective Laissez-Faire System, 1890–1940." ''Trade Unions and the State: The Construction of Industrial Relations Institutions in Britain, 1890–2000'', [[Princeton University Press]], 2005, pp.&nbsp;46–85, {{JSTOR|j.ctt7spjh.6}}.
* Leacock, Stephen. "Laissez Faire and Legislation." ''My Recollection of Chicago and the Doctrine of Laissez Faire'', edited by Carl Spadoni, [[University of Toronto Press]], 1998, pp.&nbsp;35–40, {{JSTOR|10.3138/j.ctvcj2sx8.10}}.
* Strum, Philippa. "From Laissez-faire Capitalism to Worker-Management." ''Brandeis: Beyond Progressivism'', [[University Press of Kansas]], 1993, pp.&nbsp;24–48, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctv1p2gkvd.7}}.
* Halevi, Leor. "Paper Money and Consummate Men: Capitalism and the Rise of Laissez-Faire Salafism." ''Modern Things on Trial: Islam's Global and Material Reformation in the Age of Rida, 1865–1935'', [[Columbia University Press]], 2019, pp.&nbsp;96–130, {{JSTOR|10.7312/hale18866.10}}.
* Kolozi, Peter. "In Search of the Warrior-statesman: The Critique of Laissez-Faire Capitalism by Brooks Adams and Theodore Roosevelt." ''Conservatives Against Capitalism: From the Industrial Revolution to Globalization'', [[Columbia University Press]], 2017, pp.&nbsp;51–76, {{JSTOR|10.7312/kolo16652.6}}.
* Palley, Thomas I. "Milton Friedman: The Great Laissez-Faire Partisan." ''[[Economic and Political Weekly]]'', vol. 41, no. 49, 2006, pp.&nbsp;5041–5043, {{JSTOR|4419000}}.
* Holroyd, Carin Lee. "Governments and International Trade: An Intellectual Analysis." ''Government, International Trade, and Laissez-Faire Capitalism: Canada, Australia, and New Zealand's Relations with Japan'', [[McGill-Queen's University Press]], 2002, pp.&nbsp;15–39, {{JSTOR|j.ctt7zmzz.7}}.
* Simons, Henry C., William Breit, Roger L. Ransom, and Robert M. Solow. "Radical Proponent of Laissez-faire." In ''The Academic Scribblers,'' 207–221. [[Princeton University Press]], 1998. {{doi|10.2307/j.ctt7zvbf2.18}}.
* Henry, John F. "The Ideology of the Laissez Faire Program." [[Journal of Economic Issues]], vol. 42, no. 1, [[Association for Evolutionary Economics]], 2008, pp.&nbsp;209–224, {{JSTOR|25511295}}.
* Adams, Walter, and James W. Brock. "The Impact of Economic Power Is Discussed; Public Policy Interests in Economic Liberty and Democratic Process Yield a Conundrum." Antitrust Economics on Trial: A Dialogue on the New Laissez-Faire, [[Princeton University Press]], 1991, pp.&nbsp;115–128, {{JSTOR|j.ctt7zvv8c.8}}.
* Lal, Deepak. "From Laissez Faire to the Dirigiste Dogma." Reviving the Invisible Hand: The Case for Classical Liberalism in the Twenty-First Century, [[Princeton University Press]], 2006, pp.&nbsp;48–61, {{JSTOR|j.ctt7sjk9.6}}.
* Fried, Barbara H. "The Empty Idea of Property Rights." ''The Progressive Assault on Laissez Faire: Robert Hale and the First Law and Economics Movement'', [[Harvard University Press]], 1998, pp.&nbsp;71–107, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctvk12r43.6}}.
* Rodgers, Daniel T. "Twilight of Laissez-Faire." ''Atlantic Crossings: Social Politics in a Progressive Age'', [[Harvard University Press]], 1998, pp.&nbsp;76–111, {{JSTOR|j.ctv1qdr01w.6}}.
* {{cite book |title=Free Market Criminal Justice: How Democracy and Laissez Faire Undermine the Rule of Law |author=Brown, D.K. |isbn=978-0-19-045787-7 |lccn=2015023124 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=6qbnCwAAQBAJ |year=2016 |publisher=[[Oxford University Press]] }}
* {{cite book |title=An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Europe: Economic Regimes from Laissez-Faire to Globalization |author=Berend, I.T. |isbn=978-1-139-45264-9 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=dK44ciNfx6MC |year=2006 |publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]] }}
* {{cite book |title=The Labour Constitution: The Enduring Idea of Labour Law |author=Dukes, R. |isbn=978-0-19-960169-1 |lccn=2014943656 |series=Oxford Scholarship online |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=bbqpBAAAQBAJ |year=2014 |publisher=[[Oxford University Press]] }}
* {{cite book |title=The Political Economy of Progress: John Stuart Mill and Modern Radicalism |author=Persky, J. |isbn=978-0-19-046065-5 |lccn=2016008348 |series=Oxford Studies in History of Economics |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=x9wmDAAAQBAJ |year=2016 |publisher=Oxford University Press |access-date=2022-03-11 |archive-date=2024-02-08 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208013930/https://books.google.com/books?id=x9wmDAAAQBAJ |url-status=live }}
* {{cite book |title=Government versus Markets: The Changing Economic Role of the State |author=Tanzi, V. |isbn=978-1-139-49973-6 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=0 |year=2011 |publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]] }}{{Dead link|date=June 2023 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}
* {{cite book |title=The Progressive Assault on Laissez Faire: Robert Hale and the First Law and Economics Movement |author=Fried, B. |isbn=978-0-674-03730-4 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=6U0jifXSJmsC |year=2009 |publisher=[[Harvard University Press]] |access-date=2022-03-11 |archive-date=2024-02-08 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208013817/https://books.google.com/books?id=6U0jifXSJmsC |url-status=live }}
* {{cite book |title=Economic Sentiments: Adam Smith, Condorcet, and the Enlightenment |author=[[Emma Rothschild|Rothschild, E.]] |isbn=978-0-674-72562-1 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=mtxiwxH1gf4C |year=2013 |publisher=[[Harvard University Press]] |access-date=2022-03-11 |archive-date=2024-02-08 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208013932/https://books.google.com/books?id=mtxiwxH1gf4C |url-status=live }}
* {{cite book |title=A New History of Management |last1=Cummings |first1=S. |last2=Bridgman |first2=T. |last3=Hassard |first3=J. |last4=Rowlinson |first4=M. |isbn=978-1-107-13814-8 |lccn=2017012133 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=AB4xDwAAQBAJ |year=2017 |publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]] |access-date=2022-03-11 |archive-date=2024-02-08 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208013941/https://books.google.com/books?id=AB4xDwAAQBAJ |url-status=live }}
* {{cite book |title=My Recollection of Chicago; And, The Doctrine of Laissez Faire |last1=Leacock |first1=S. |last2=Spadoni |first2=C. |isbn=978-0-8020-8121-6 |lccn=99172372 |series=G – Reference, Information and Interdisciplinary Subjects Series |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=9Ye0zgEACAAJ |year=1998 |publisher=[[University of Toronto Press]] |access-date=2022-03-11 |archive-date=2024-02-08 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208013819/https://books.google.com/books?id=9Ye0zgEACAAJ |url-status=live }}
* {{cite book |title=The Political Theory of Neoliberalism |author=Biebricher, T. |isbn=978-1-5036-0783-5 |lccn=2018016758 |series=Currencies: New Thinking for Financial Times |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=J7WIDwAAQBAJ |year=2019 |publisher=[[Stanford University Press]] |access-date=2022-03-11 |archive-date=2024-02-08 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208013826/https://books.google.com/books?id=J7WIDwAAQBAJ |url-status=live }}
* {{cite book |title=Essays on the Intellectual History of Economics |last1=Viner |first1=J. |last2=Irwin |first2=D.A. |isbn=978-1-4008-6205-4 |series=Princeton Legacy Library |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=_TAABAAAQBAJ |year=2014 |publisher=[[Princeton University Press]] |access-date=2022-10-25 |archive-date=2022-10-25 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221025175929/https://books.google.com/books?id=_TAABAAAQBAJ |url-status=live }}
* {{cite book |title=Selected Essays by Frank H. Knight, Volume 2: Laissez Faire: Pro and Con |author-link1=Frank Knight |last1=Knight |first1=Frank |last2=Emmett |first2=R.B. |isbn=978-0-226-44697-4 |lccn=98053133 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=AGD0jfS4UToC |year=1999 |publisher=[[University of Chicago Press]] |access-date=2022-03-11 |archive-date=2024-02-08 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208013826/https://books.google.com/books?id=AGD0jfS4UToC |url-status=live }}
* {{cite book |title=Milton Friedman on Economics: Selected Papers |author-link1=Milton Friedman |last1=Friedman |first1=Milton |author-link2=Leonard Jimmie Savage |last2=Savage |first2=Leonard Jimmie |author-link3=Gary Becker |last3=Becker |first3=Gary |isbn=978-0-226-26349-6 |lccn=2007031094 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=UEMZ3bKKVSgC |year=2007 |publisher=[[University of Chicago Press]] |access-date=2022-03-11 |archive-date=2024-02-08 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208013932/https://books.google.com/books?id=UEMZ3bKKVSgC |url-status=live }}
{{refend}}

== External links ==
{{Wiktionary}}
{{wikiquote}}
{{Spoken Wikipedia|date=27 June 2008|en-us-laissez-faire.ogg}}
* [https://www.britannica.com/topic/laissez-faire Laissez-faire] at ''[[Encyclopædia Britannica]]'' Online.


{{aspects of capitalism}}
[[Category:Economic ideologies]]
{{economic liberalism}}
[[Category:Libertarianism]]
{{Liberalism}}
{{libertarianism}}
{{Authority control}}


[[de:Laissez-faire]]
{{DEFAULTSORT:Laissez-Faire}}
[[Category:Capitalism]]
[[et:Laissez faire]]
[[Category:Classical liberalism]]
[[es:Laissez faire]]
[[Category:Conservatism]]
[[fr:Laissez-faire]]
[[Category:Economic history of France]]
[[it:Laissez-faire]]
[[Category:Economic liberalism]]
[[he:לסה פר]]
[[Category:Ideologies of capitalism]]
[[nl:Laissez-faire]]
[[Category:Individualism]]
[[ja:レッセフェール]]
[[Category:Market socialism]]
[[no:Laissez-faire]]
[[pl:Leseferyzm]]
[[Category:Minarchism]]
[[Category:Neoliberalism]]
[[pt:Laissez-faire]]
[[Category:Political movements]]
[[ru:Laissez-faire]]
[[Category:Political theories]]
[[sco:Laissez-faire]]
[[Category:Right-wing politics]]
[[simple:Laissez faire]]
[[Category:Right-libertarianism]]
[[sk:Laissez-faire]]
[[sr:Лесе фер]]
[[fi:Laissez-faire]]
[[sv:Laissez faire]]
[[tr:Laissez faire]]
[[zh:自由放任]]

Latest revision as of 01:48, 10 May 2024

Laissez-faire (/ˌlɛsˈfɛər/ LESS-ay-FAIR; from French: laissez faire [lɛse fɛːʁ] , lit.'let do') is a type of economic system in which transactions between private groups of people are free from any form of economic interventionism (such as subsidies or regulations). As a system of thought, laissez-faire rests on the following axioms: "the individual is the basic unit in society, i.e., the standard of measurement in social calculus; the individual has a natural right to freedom; and the physical order of nature is a harmonious and self-regulating system."[1] The original phrase was laissez faire, laissez passer, with the second part meaning "let (things) pass". It is generally attributed to Vincent de Gournay.[2]

Another basic principle of laissez-faire holds that markets should naturally be competitive, a rule that the early advocates of laissez-faire always emphasized.[1]

The Physiocrats were early advocates of laissez-faire and advocated for a impôt unique, a tax on land rent to replace the "monstrous and crippling network of taxation that had grown up in 17th century France".[3] Their view was that only land should be taxed because land is not produced but a naturally existing resource, meaning a tax on it wouldn't be taking from the labour of the taxed, unlike most other taxes.[4][clarification needed]

Proponents of laissez-faire argue for a near complete separation of government from the economic sector.[5][verification needed] The phrase laissez-faire is part of a larger French phrase and literally translates to "let [it/them] do", but in this context the phrase usually means to "let it be" and in expression "laid back".[6] Although never practiced with full consistency, laissez-faire capitalism emerged in the mid-18th century and was further popularized by Adam Smith's book The Wealth of Nations.[7][8]

Etymology and usage[edit]

The term laissez-faire likely originated in a meeting that took place around 1681 between powerful French Controller-General of Finances Jean-Baptiste Colbert and a group of French businessmen headed by M. Le Gendre. When the eager mercantilist minister asked how the French state could be of service to the merchants and help promote their commerce, Le Gendre replied simply: "Laissez-nous faire" ("Leave it to us" or "Let us do [it]", the French verb not requiring an object).[9]

The anecdote on the Colbert–Le Gendre meeting appeared in a 1751 article in the Journal économique, written by French minister and champion of free trade René de Voyer, Marquis d'Argenson—also the first known appearance of the term in print.[10] Argenson himself had used the phrase earlier (1736) in his own diaries in a famous outburst:

Laissez faire, telle devrait être la devise de toute puissance publique, depuis que le monde est civilisé [...]. Détestable principe que celui de ne vouloir grandir que par l'abaissement de nos voisins ! Il n'y a que la méchanceté et la malignité du cœur de satisfaites dans ce principe, et l'intérêt y est opposé. Laissez faire, morbleu ! Laissez faire !![11]

Let go, which should be the motto of all public power, since the world was civilized [...]. [It is] a detestable principle of those that want to enlarge [themselves] but by the abasement of our neighbours. There is but the wicked and the malignant heart[s] [who are] satisfied by this principle and [its] interest is opposed. Let go, for God's sake! Let go!![12]

— René Louis de Voyer de Paulmy d'Argenson

Vincent de Gournay, a French Physiocrat and intendant of commerce in the 1750s, popularized the term laissez-faire as he allegedly adopted it from François Quesnay's writings on China.[13] Quesnay coined the phrases laissez-faire and laissez-passer,[14] laissez-faire being a translation of the Chinese term wu wei (無為).[15] Gournay ardently supported the removal of restrictions on trade and the deregulation of industry in France. Delighted with the Colbert–Le Gendre anecdote,[16] he forged it into a larger maxim all his own: "Laissez faire et laissez passer" ("Let do and let pass"). His motto has also been identified as the longer "Laissez faire et laissez passer, le monde va de lui même !" ("Let do and let pass, the world goes on by itself!"). Although Gournay left no written tracts on his economic policy ideas, he had immense personal influence on his contemporaries, notably his fellow Physiocrats, who credit both the laissez-faire slogan and the doctrine to Gournay.[17]

Before d'Argenson or Gournay, P. S. de Boisguilbert had enunciated the phrase "On laisse faire la nature" ("Let nature run its course").[18] D'Argenson himself during his life was better known for the similar, but less-celebrated motto "Pas trop gouverner" ("Govern not too much").[19]

The Physiocrats proclaimed laissez-faire in 18th-century France, placing it at the very core of their economic principles and famous economists, beginning with Adam Smith, developed the idea.[20] It is with the Physiocrats and the classical political economy that the term laissez-faire is ordinarily associated.[21] The book Laissez Faire and the General-Welfare State states: "The physiocrats, reacting against the excessive mercantilist regulations of the France of their day, expressed a belief in a 'natural order' or liberty under which individuals in following their selfish interests contributed to the general good. Since, in their view, this natural order functioned successfully without the aid of government, they advised the state to restrict itself to upholding the rights of private property and individual liberty, to removing all artificial barriers to trade, and to abolishing all useless laws."[20]

The French phrase laissez-faire gained currency in English-speaking countries with the spread of Physiocratic literature in the late 18th century. George Whatley's 1774 Principles of Trade (co-authored with Benjamin Franklin) re-told the Colbert-LeGendre anecdote; this may mark the first appearance of the phrase in an English-language publication.[22]

Herbert Spencer was opposed to a slightly different application of laissez faire—to "that miserable laissez-faire" that leads to men's ruin, saying: "Along with that miserable laissez-faire which calmly looks on while men ruin themselves in trying to enforce by law their equitable claims, there goes activity in supplying them, at other men's cost, with gratis novel-reading!"[23]

As a product of the Enlightenment, laissez-faire was "conceived as the way to unleash human potential through the restoration of a natural system, a system unhindered by the restrictions of government".[1] In a similar vein, Adam Smith[when?] viewed the economy as a natural system and the market as an organic part of that system. Smith saw laissez-faire as a moral program and the market its instrument to ensure men the rights of natural law.[1] By extension, free markets become a reflection of the natural system of liberty.[1] For Smith, laissez-faire was "a program for the abolition of laws constraining the market, a program for the restoration of order and for the activation of potential growth".[1]

However, Smith[24] and notable classical economists such as Thomas Malthus and David Ricardo did not use the phrase. Jeremy Bentham used the term, but it was probably[original research?] James Mill's reference to the laissez-faire maxim (together with the "Pas trop gouverner" motto) in an 1824 entry for the Encyclopædia Britannica that really brought the term into wider English usage. With the advent of the Anti-Corn Law League (founded 1838), the term received much of its English meaning.[25][need quotation to verify]

Smith first used the metaphor of an invisible hand in his book The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759) to describe the unintentional effects of economic self-organization from economic self-interest.[26] Although not the metaphor itself, the idea lying behind the invisible hand belongs to Bernard de Mandeville and his Fable of the Bees (1705). In political economy, that idea and the doctrine of laissez-faire have long been closely related.[27] Some have characterized the invisible-hand metaphor as one for laissez-faire,[28] although Smith never actually used the term himself.[24] In Third Millennium Capitalism (2000), Wyatt M. Rogers Jr. notes a trend whereby recently "conservative politicians and economists have chosen the term 'free-market capitalism' in lieu of laissez-faire".[29]

American individualist anarchists such as Benjamin Tucker saw themselves as economic laissez-faire socialists and political individualists while arguing that their "anarchistic socialism" or "individual anarchism" was "consistent Manchesterism".[30]

History[edit]

Europe[edit]

In Europe, the laissez-faire movement was first widely promoted by the Physiocrats, a movement that included Vincent de Gournay (1712–1759), a successful merchant turned political figure. Gournay is postulated to have adapted the Taoist concept wu wei,[31] from the writings on China by François Quesnay[15] (1694–1774). Gournay held that government should allow the laws of nature to govern economic activity, with the state only intervening to protect life, liberty and property. François Quesnay and Anne Robert Jacques Turgot, Baron de l'Aulne took up Gournay's ideas. Quesnay had the ear of the King of France, Louis XV and in 1754 persuaded him to give laissez-faire a try. On September 17, the King abolished all tolls and restraints on the sale and transport of grain. For more than a decade, the experiment appeared successful, but 1768 saw a poor harvest, and the cost of bread rose so high that there was widespread starvation while merchants exported grain to obtain the best profit. In 1770, the Comptroller-General of Finances Joseph Marie Terray revoked the edict allowing free trade in grain.[32]

The doctrine of laissez-faire became an integral part of 19th-century European liberalism.[20] Just as liberals supported freedom of thought in the intellectual sphere, so were they equally prepared to champion the principles of free trade and free competition in the sphere of economics, seeing the state as merely a passive policeman, protecting private property and administering justice, but not interfering with the affairs of its citizens. Businessmen, British industrialists in particular, were quick to associate these principles with their own economic interests.[20] Many of the ideas of the physiocrats spread throughout Europe and were adopted to a greater or lesser extent in Sweden, Tuscany, Spain and in the newly created United States. Adam Smith, author of The Wealth of Nations (1776), met Quesnay and acknowledged his influence.[33]

In Britain, the newspaper The Economist (founded in 1843) became an influential voice for laissez-faire capitalism.[34] Laissez-faire advocates opposed food aid for famines occurring within the British Empire. In 1847, referring to the famine then underway in Ireland, founder of The Economist James Wilson wrote: "It is no man's business to provide for another".[35] More specifically, in An Essay on the Principle of Population, Malthus argued that there was nothing that could be done to avoid famines because he felt he had mathematically proven that population growth tends to exceed growth in food production. However, The Economist campaigned against the Corn Laws that protected landlords in the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Ireland against competition from less expensive foreign imports of cereal products. The Great Famine in Ireland in 1845 led to the repeal of the Corn Laws in 1846. The tariffs on grain which kept the price of bread artificially high were repealed.[36] However, repeal of the Corn Laws came too late to stop the Irish famine, partly because it was done in stages over three years.[37]

A group that became known as the Manchester Liberals, to which Richard Cobden (1804–1865) and John Bright (1811–1889) belonged, were staunch defenders of free trade. After the death of Cobden, the Cobden Club (founded in 1866) continued their work.[38] The breakdown of laissez-faire as practised by the British Empire was partly led by British companies eager for state support of their positions abroad, in particular British oil companies.[39]

In Italy, philosopher Benedetto Croce created the term "liberism" (derived from the Italian term liberismo), a term for the economic doctrine of laissez-faire capitalism; it is synonymous with economic liberalism. He claimed that "Liberalism can prove only a temporary right of private propriety of land and industries."[40] It was popularized in English by Italian political scientist Giovanni Sartori.[41] Sartori specifically imported the term from Italian to distinguish between social liberalism, which is generally considered a political ideology often advocating extensive government intervention in the economy, and those economic liberal theories that propose to virtually eliminate such intervention. In informal usage, liberism overlaps with other concepts such as free trade, neoliberalism, right-libertarianism, the American concept of libertarianism,[42] and the laissez-faire doctrine of the French liberal Doctrinaires. The intention of Croce and of Sartori to attack the right to private property and to free enterprise separating them from the general philosophy of liberalism, that is primarily a theory of natural rights, was always criticised openly by the quoted philosophers and by some of the main representatives of liberalism, such as Luigi Einaudi, Friedrich Hayek,[42][43][44] and Milton Friedman.[45] The Austrian School economist Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk argues that the differences between the economical concept of liberism[46] and the economical consequences of liberalism[47][48] can be summarized by saying that "A market is a law system. Without it, the only possible economy is the street robbery."[49]

United States[edit]

Frank Bourgin's study of the Constitutional Convention and subsequent decades argues that direct government involvement in the economy was intended by the Founding Fathers.[50] The reason for this was the economic and financial chaos the nation suffered under the Articles of Confederation. The goal was to ensure that dearly-won political independence was not lost by being economically and financially dependent on the powers and princes of Europe. The creation of a strong central government able to promote science, invention, industry and commerce was seen as an essential means of promoting the general welfare and making the economy of the United States strong enough for them to determine their own destiny. Others view Bourgin's study, written in the 1940s and not published until 1989, as an over-interpretation of the evidence, intended originally to defend the New Deal and later to counter Ronald Reagan's economic policies.[51]

Historian Kathleen G. Donohue argues that in the 19th century liberalism in the United States had distinctive characteristics and that "at the center of classical liberal theory [in Europe] was the idea of laissez-faire. To the vast majority of American classical liberals, however, laissez-faire did not mean "no government intervention" at all. On the contrary, they were more than willing to see government provide tariffs, railroad subsidies, and internal improvements, all of which benefited producers". Notable examples of government intervention in the period prior to the American Civil War include the establishment of the Patent Office in 1802; the establishment of the Office of Standard Weights and Measures in 1830; the creation of the Survey of the Coast (later renamed the United States Coast Survey and then the United States Coast and Geodetic Survey) in 1807 and other measures to improve river and harbor navigation; the various Army expeditions to the west, beginning with Lewis and Clark's Corps of Discovery in 1804 and continuing into the 1870s, almost always under the direction of an officer from the Army Corps of Topographical Engineers and which provided crucial information for the overland pioneers that followed; the assignment of Army Engineer officers to assist or direct the surveying and construction of the early railroads and canals; and the establishment of the First Bank of the United States and Second Bank of the United States as well as various protectionist measures (e.g. the tariff of 1828). Several of these proposals met with serious opposition and required a great deal of horse-trading to be enacted into law. For instance, the First National Bank would not have reached the desk of President George Washington in the absence of an agreement that was reached between Alexander Hamilton and several Southern members of Congress to locate the capitol in the District of Columbia. In contrast to Hamilton and the Federalists was Thomas Jefferson and James Madison's opposing political party, the Democratic-Republicans.

Most of the early opponents of laissez-faire capitalism in the United States subscribed to the American School. This school of thought was inspired by the ideas of Hamilton, who proposed the creation of a government-sponsored bank and increased tariffs to favor Northern industrial interests. Following Hamilton's death, the more abiding protectionist influence in the antebellum period came from Henry Clay and his American System. In the early 19th century, "it is quite clear that the laissez-faire label is an inappropriate one" to apply to the relationship between the United States government and industry.[52] In the mid-19th century, the United States followed the Whig tradition of economic nationalism, which included increased state control, regulation and macroeconomic development of infrastructure.[53] Public works such as the provision and regulation transportation such as railroads took effect. The Pacific Railway Acts provided the development of the First transcontinental railroad.[53][54] To help pay for its war effort in the Civil War, the United States government imposed its first personal income tax on 5 August 1861 as part of the Revenue Act of 1861 (3% of all incomes over US$800; rescinded in 1872).

Following the Civil War, the movement towards a mixed economy accelerated. Protectionism increased with the McKinley Tariff of 1890 and the Dingley Tariff of 1897. Government regulation of the economy expanded with the enactment of the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887 and the Sherman Anti-trust Act. The Progressive Era saw the enactment of more controls on the economy as evidenced by the Woodrow Wilson administration's New Freedom program. Following World War I and the Great Depression, the United States turned to a mixed economy which combined free enterprise with a progressive income tax and in which from time to time the government stepped in to support and protect American industry from competition from overseas. For example, in the 1980s the government sought to protect the automobile industry by "voluntary" export restrictions from Japan.[55]

In 1986, Pietro S. Nivola wrote: "By and large, the comparative strength of the dollar against major foreign currencies has reflected high U.S. interest rates driven by huge federal budget deficits. Hence, the source of much of the current deterioration of trade is not the general state of the economy, but rather the government's mix of fiscal and monetary policies – that is, the problematic juxtaposition of bold tax reductions, relatively tight monetary targets, generous military outlays, and only modest cuts in major entitlement programs. Put simply, the roots of the trade problem and of the resurgent protectionism it has fomented are fundamentally political as well as economic".[56]

A more recent advocate of total laissez-faire has been Objectivist Ayn Rand, who described it as "the abolition of any and all forms of government intervention in production and trade, the separation of State and Economics, in the same way and for the same reasons as the separation of Church and State".[57] This viewpoint is summed up in what is known as the iron law of regulation, which is a theory stating that all government economic regulation eventually leads to a net loss in social welfare.[58] Rand's political philosophy emphasized individual rights (including property rights)[59] and she considered laissez-faire capitalism the only moral social system because in her view it was the only system based on the protection of those rights.[60] She opposed statism, which she understood to include theocracy, absolute monarchy, Nazism, fascism, communism, socialism and dictatorship.[61] Rand believed that natural rights should be enforced by a constitutionally limited government.[62] Although her political views are often classified as conservative or libertarian, she preferred the term "radical for capitalism". She worked with conservatives on political projects, but disagreed with them over issues such as religion and ethics.[63] She denounced libertarianism, which she associated with anarchism.[64] She rejected anarchism as a naïve theory based in subjectivism that could only lead to collectivism in practice.[65]

Models[edit]

Capitalism[edit]

A closely related name for laissez-faire capitalism is that of raw, pure, or unrestrained capitalism, which refers to capitalism free of any regulations,[66] with low or minimal[67] government and operating almost entirely on the profit motive. It shares a similar economic conception with anarcho-capitalism.

Advocates of laissez-faire capitalism argue that it relies on a constitutionally limited government that unconditionally bans the initiation of force and coercion, including fraud. Therefore, free market economists such as Milton Friedman and Thomas Sowell argue that, under such a system, relationships between companies and workers are purely voluntary and mistreated workers will seek better treatment elsewhere. Thus, most companies will compete for workers on the basis of pay, benefits, and work-life balance just as they compete with one another in the marketplace on the basis of the relative cost and quality of their goods.[68][non-primary source needed][69][non-primary source needed]

So-called "raw" or "hyper-capitalism" is a major motif of cyberpunk in dystopian works such as Syndicate.[70][71]

Socialism[edit]

Although laissez-faire has been commonly associated with capitalism, there is a similar laissez-faire economic theory and system associated with socialism called left-wing laissez-faire,[72][73] or free-market anarchism, also known as free-market anti-capitalism and free-market socialism to distinguish it from laissez-faire capitalism.[74][75][76] One first example of this is mutualism as developed by Pierre-Joseph Proudhon in the 18th century, from which emerged individualist anarchism. Benjamin Tucker is one eminent American individualist anarchist who adopted a laissez-faire system he termed anarchistic socialism in contraposition to state socialism.[77][78] This tradition has been recently associated with contemporary scholars such as Kevin Carson,[79][80] Roderick T. Long,[81][82] Charles W. Johnson,[83] Brad Spangler,[84] Sheldon Richman,[85][86][87] Chris Matthew Sciabarra[88] and Gary Chartier,[89] who stress the value of radically free markets, termed freed markets to distinguish them from the common conception which these left-libertarians believe to be riddled with capitalist and statist privileges.[90] Referred to as left-wing market anarchists[91] or market-oriented left-libertarians,[87] proponents of this approach strongly affirm the classical liberal ideas of self-ownership and free markets while maintaining that taken to their logical conclusions these ideas support anti-capitalist, anti-corporatist, anti-hierarchical and pro-labor positions in economics; anti-imperialism in foreign policy; and thoroughly radical views regarding such cultural issues as gender, sexuality and race.[92][93] Critics of laissez-faire as commonly understood argues that a truly laissez-faire system would be anti-capitalist and socialist.[94][95]

Kevin Carson describes his politics as on "the outer fringes of both free market libertarianism and socialism"[96] and has also been highly critical of intellectual property.[97] Carson has identified the work of Benjamin Tucker, Thomas Hodgskin, Ralph Borsodi, Paul Goodman, Lewis Mumford, Elinor Ostrom, Peter Kropotkin and Ivan Illich as sources of inspiration for his approach to politics and economics.[98] In addition to individualist anarchist Benjamin Tucker's big four monopolies (land, money, tariffs and patents), he argues that the state has also transferred wealth to the wealthy by subsidizing organizational centralization in the form of transportation and communication subsidies. Carson believes that Tucker overlooked this issue due to Tucker's focus on individual market transactions whereas he also focuses on organizational issues. As such, the primary focus of his most recent work has been decentralized manufacturing and the informal and household economies.[99] The theoretical sections of Carson's Studies in Mutualist Political Economy are also presented as an attempt to integrate marginalist critiques into the labor theory of value.[100]

In response to claims that he uses the term capitalism incorrectly, Carson says he is deliberately choosing to resurrect what he claims to be an old definition of the term to "make a point". He claims that "the term 'capitalism,' as it was originally used, did not refer to a free market, but to a type of statist class system in which capitalists controlled the state and the state intervened in the market on their behalf".[101] Carson holds that "capitalism, arising as a new class society directly from the old class society of the Middle Ages, was founded on an act of robbery as massive as the earlier feudal conquest of the land. It has been sustained to the present by continual state intervention to protect its system of privilege without which its survival is unimaginable".[102] Carson argues that in a truly laissez-faire system the ability to extract a profit from labor and capital would be negligible.[103] Carson coined the pejorative term vulgar libertarianism, a phrase that describes the use of a free market rhetoric in defense of corporate capitalism and economic inequality. According to Carson, the term is derived from the phrase vulgar political economy which Karl Marx described as an economic order that "deliberately becomes increasingly apologetic and makes strenuous attempts to talk out of existence the ideas which contain the contradictions [existing in economic life]".[104]

Gary Chartier offers an understanding of property rights as contingent yet tightly constrained social strategies, reflective of the importance of multiple, overlapping rationales for separate ownership and of natural law principles of practical reasonableness, defending robust yet non-absolute protections for these rights in a manner similar to that employed by David Hume.[105] This account is distinguished both from Lockean and neo-Lockean views which deduce property rights from the idea of self-ownership and from consequentialist accounts that might license widespread ad hoc interference with the possessions of groups and individuals.[106] Chartier uses this account to ground a clear statement of the natural law basis for the view that solidaristic wealth redistribution by individual persons is often morally required, but as a response by individuals and grass-roots networks to particular circumstances rather than as a state-driven attempt to achieve a particular distributive pattern.[107] He advances detailed arguments for workplace democracy rooted in such natural law principles as subsidiarity,[108] defending it as morally desirable and as a likely outcome of the elimination of injustice rather than as something to be mandated by the state.[109]

Chartier has discussed natural law approaches to land reform and to the occupation of factories by workers.[110] He objects on natural law grounds to intellectual property protections, drawing on his theory of property rights more generally[111] and develops a general natural law account of boycotts.[112] He has argued that proponents of genuinely freed markets should explicitly reject capitalism and identify with the global anti-capitalist movement while emphasizing that the abuses the anti-capitalist movement highlights result from state-tolerated violence and state-secured privilege rather than from voluntary cooperation and exchange. According to Chartier, "it makes sense for [freed-market advocates] to name what they oppose 'capitalism.' Doing so calls attention to the freedom movement's radical roots, emphasizes the value of understanding society as an alternative to the state, underscores the fact that proponents of freedom object to non-aggressive as well as aggressive restraints on liberty, ensures that advocates of freedom aren't confused with people who use market rhetoric to prop up an unjust status quo, and expresses solidarity between defenders of freed markets and workers — as well as ordinary people around the world who use "capitalism" as a short-hand label for the world-system that constrains their freedom and stunts their lives".[102][113]

Criticism[edit]

Over the years, a number of economists have offered critiques of laissez-faire economics. Adam Smith acknowledges some moral ambiguities towards the system of capitalism.[114] Smith had misgivings concerning some aspects of each of the major character-types produced by modern capitalist society, namely the landlords, the workers and the capitalists.[114] Smith claimed that "[t]he landlords' role in the economic process is passive. Their ability to reap a revenue solely from ownership of land tends to make them indolent and inept, and so they tend to be unable to even look after their own economic interests"[114] and that "[t]he increase in population should increase the demand for food, which should increase rents, which should be economically beneficial to the landlords". According to Smith, the landlords should be in favour of policies which contribute to the growth in the wealth of nations, but they often are not in favour of these pro-growth policies because of their own indolent-induced ignorance and intellectual flabbiness.[114] Smith stated clearly that he believed that without morality and laws, society would fail. From that perspective, it seems dubious that Smith supported a pure Laissez-Faire style of capitalism, and the ideas he supports in The Wealth of Nations is heavily dependent on the moral philosophy from his previous work, Theory of Moral Sentiment.[115]

Many philosophers have written on the systems society has created to manage their civilizations. Thomas Hobbes used the concept of a "state of nature", which is a time before any government or laws, as a starting point to consider the question. In this time, life would be "war of all against all". Further, "In such condition, there is no place for industry; because the fruit thereof is uncertain ... continual fear and danger of violent death, and the life of man solitary, poor, nasty, brutish, and short."[116]

Regardless of preferred political preference, all societies require shared moral values as a prerequisite on which to build laws to protect individuals from each other. Adam Smith wrote Wealth of Nations during the Enlightenment, a period of time when the prevailing attitude was, "All things can be Known." In effect, European thinkers, inspired by the likes of Isaac Newton and others, set about to "find the laws" of all things, that there existed a "natural law" underlying all aspects of life. They believed that these could be discovered and that everything in the universe could be rationally demystified and catalogued, including human interactions.[117]

Critics and market abolitionists such as David McNally argue in the Marxist tradition that the logic of the market inherently produces inequitable outcomes and leads to unequal exchanges, arguing that Smith's moral intent and moral philosophy espousing equal exchange was undermined by the practice of the free market he championed. According to McNally, the development of the market economy involved coercion, exploitation and violence that Smith's moral philosophy could not countenance.[118]

The British economist John Maynard Keynes condemned laissez-faire economic policy on several occasions.[119] In The End of Laissez-faire (1926), one of the most famous of his critiques, Keynes argues that the doctrines of laissez-faire are dependent to some extent on improper deductive reasoning and says the question of whether a market solution or state intervention is better must be determined on a case-by-case basis.[120]

The Austrian School economist Friedrich Hayek stated that a freely competitive, laissez-faire banking industry tends to be endogenously destabilizing and pro-cyclical, arguing that the need for central banking control was inescapable.[121]

Karl Polanyi's Great Transformation criticizes self-regulating markets as aberrational, unnatural phenomena which tend towards social disruption.[122][123]

In modern economics laissez-faire typically has a bad connotation, which hints towards a perceived need for restraint due to social needs and securities that can not be adequately responded to by companies with just a motive for making profit.

Robert Kuttner states that "for over a century, popular struggles in democracies have used the nation-state to temper raw capitalism. The power of voters has offset the power of capital. But as national barriers have come down in the name of freer commerce, so has the capacity of governments to manage capitalism in a broad public interest. So the real issue is not 'trade' but democratic governance".[124]

The main issues of raw capitalism are said to lie in its disregard for quality, durability, sustainability, respect for the environment and human beings as well as a lack of morality.[125] From this more critical angle, companies might naturally aim to maximise profits at the expense of workers' and broader social interests.[126]

See also[edit]

References[edit]

  1. ^ a b c d e f Gaspard, Toufick. A Political Economy of Lebanon 1948–2002: The Limits of Laissez-faire. Boston: Brill, 2004. ISBN 978-90-04-13259-7[page needed]
  2. ^ Ellen Judy Wilson; Peter Hanns Reill (1 August 2004). Encyclopedia Of The Enlightenment. Infobase Publishing. p. 241. ISBN 978-0-8160-5335-3. Archived from the original on 23 July 2023. Retrieved 21 July 2012.
  3. ^ Rothbard, Murray (1995). An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought. Edward Elgar Publishing. p. 371. ISBN 0-945466-48-X.
  4. ^ Gaffney, Mason. "The Taxable Surplus of Land: Measuring, Guarding and Gathering It". Archived from the original on 10 May 2015. Retrieved 9 December 2014.
  5. ^ Quick Reference Handbook Set, Basic Knowledge and Modern Technology (revised) by Edward H. Litchfield, PhD
  6. ^ "Laissez-faire" Archived 2015-09-27 at the Wayback Machine, Business Dictionary.
  7. ^ Edward H. Litchfield. "Quick Reference Handbook Set, Basic Knowledge and Modern Technology" (revised ed.).
  8. ^ "Adam Smith". Encyclopædia Britannica. Archived from the original on 12 April 2020. Retrieved 12 April 2020.
  9. ^ "Journal Oeconomique" Archived 2020-04-30 at the Wayback Machine. 1751 article by the French minister of finance.
  10. ^ M. d'Argenson, "Lettre au sujet de la dissertation sur le commerce du marquis de Belloni', Avril 1751, Journal Oeconomique p. 111 Archived 2022-10-26 at the Wayback Machine. See A. Oncken, Die Maxime Laissez faire et laissez passer, ihr Ursprung, ihr Werden, 1866
  11. ^ As quoted in J. M. Keynes, 1926, "The End of Laissez Faire". Argenson's Mémoirs were published only in 1858, ed. Jannet, Tome V, p. 362. See A. Oncken (Die Maxime Laissez faire et laissez passer, ihr Ursprung, ihr Werden, 1866).
  12. ^ Original somewhat literal translation using the French Wiktionary Archived 2019-06-05 at the Wayback Machine.
  13. ^ Baghdiantz McCabe, Ina (2008). Orientalism in Early Modern France: Eurasian Trade Exoticism and the Ancien Regime. Berg Publishers. pp. 271–272. ISBN 978-1-84520-374-0.
  14. ^ "Encyclopædia Britannica". Encyclopædia Britannica, Inc. 31 May 2023. Archived from the original on 22 May 2015. Retrieved 23 June 2022.
  15. ^ a b Clarke, J. J. (1997). Oriental Enlightenment: The Encounter Between Asian and Western Thought. Routledge. p. 50. ISBN 978-0-415-13376-0.
  16. ^ According to J. Turgot's "Eloge de Vincent de Gournay," Mercure, August, 1759 (repr. in Oeuvres of Turgot, vol. 1 p. 288 Archived 2022-11-12 at the Wayback Machine.
  17. ^ Gournay was credited with the phrase by Jacques Turgot ("Eloge a Gournay", Mercure 1759), the Marquis de Mirabeau (Philosophie rurale 1763 and Ephémérides du Citoyen, 1767.), the Comte d'Albon ("Éloge Historique de M. Quesnay", Nouvelles Ephémérides Économiques, May, 1775, pp. 136–137) and DuPont de Nemours (Introduction to Oeuvres de Jacques Turgot, 1808–11, Vol. I, pp. 257, 259, Daire ed.) among others.
  18. ^ "Tant, encore une fois, qu'on laisse faire la nature, on ne doit rien craindre de pareil", P.S. de Boisguilbert, 1707, Dissertation de la nature des richesses, de l'argent et des tributs.
  19. ^ DuPont de Nemours, op cit, p. 258. Oncken (op.cit) and Keynes (op.cit.) also credit the Marquis d'Argenson with the phrase "Pour gouverner mieux, il faudrait gouverner moins" ("To govern best, one needs to govern less"), possibly the source of the famous "That government is best which governs least" motto popular in American circles, attributed variously to Thomas Paine, Thomas Jefferson and Henry Thoreau.
  20. ^ a b c d Fine, Sidney. Laissez Faire and the General-Welfare State. United States: The University of Michigan Press, 1964. Print
  21. ^ Macgregor, Economic Thought and Policy (London, 1949), pp. 54–67
  22. ^ Whatley's Principles of Trade are reprinted in Works of Benjamin Franklin, Vol.2, p. 401 Archived 2022-11-12 at the Wayback Machine.
  23. ^ Justice Part IV of Ethics (1892). p. 44.
  24. ^ a b Roy C. Smith, Adam Smith and the Origins of American Enterprise: How the Founding Fathers Turned to a Great Economist's Writings and Created the American Economy, Macmillan, 2004, ISBN 0-312-32576-2, pp. 13–14.
  25. ^ Abbott P. Usher; et al. (1931). "Economic History – The Decline of Laissez Faire". American Economic Review. 22 (1, supplement): 3–10.
  26. ^ Andres Marroquin, Invisible Hand: The Wealth of Adam Smith, The Minerva Group, Inc., 2002, ISBN 1-4102-0288-7, p. 123.
  27. ^ John Eatwell, The Invisible Hand, W. W. Norton & Company, 1989, pp. Preface, x1.
  28. ^ The mathematical century: the 30 greatest problems of the last 100 years (2006) Piergiorgio Odifreddi, Arturo Sangalli, Freeman J Dyson, p. 122. Princeton University Press. 22 October 2006. ISBN 978-0-691-12805-4. Retrieved 30 July 2013.
  29. ^ Rogers, Wyatt M. (2000). "1: Economic Forces in Modern Capitalism". Third Millennium Capitalism: Convergence of Economic, Energy, and Environmental Forces. ABC-Clio ebook. Westport, Connecticut: Greenwood Publishing Group. p. 38. ISBN 978-1-56720-360-8. Retrieved 30 December 2016.
  30. ^ Tucker, Benjamin (1926). Individual Liberty: Selections from the Writings of Benjamin R. Tucker. New York: Vanguard Press. pp. 1–19.[ISBN missing]
  31. ^ Christian Gerlach, Wu-Wei in Europe. A Study of Eurasian Economic Thought Archived 2020-08-03 at the Wayback Machine, London School of Economics – March 2005 p. 3" the diffusion of wu-wei, co-evolved with the inner-European laissez-faire principle, the Libaniusian model." p. 8 "Thus, wu-wei has to be recognized as a laissez-faire instrument of Chinese political economy "p. 10 "Practising wu-wei erzhi. Consequently, it is this variant of the laissez-faire maxim in which the basis of Physiocracy's 'moral philosophy' is to be located. Priddat's work made clear that the wu-wei of the complete économie has to be considered central to Physiocracy; "p. 11 "that wu-wei translates into French as laissez-faire".
  32. ^ Will & Ariel Durant, Rousseau and the Revolution, pp. 71–77, Simon and Schuster, 1967, ISBN 0-671-63058-X.
  33. ^ Will & Ariel Durant, Rousseau and the Revolution, p. 76, Simon and Schuster, 1967, ISBN 0-671-63058-X.
  34. ^ Scott Gordon (1955). "The London Economist and the High Tide of Laissez Faire". Journal of Political Economy. 63 (6): 461–488. doi:10.1086/257722. S2CID 154921783.
  35. ^ Cormac Ó Gráda (1995). "section: Ideology and relief in Chpt. 2". The Great Irish Famine. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-55787-0.
  36. ^ George Miller. On Fairness and Efficiency. The Policy Press, 2000. ISBN 978-1-86134-221-8 p. 344
  37. ^ Christine Kinealy. A Death-Dealing Famine:The Great Hunger in Ireland. Pluto Press, 1997. ISBN 978-0-7453-1074-9. p. 59.
  38. ^ Antonia Taddei (1999). "London Clubs in the Late Nineteenth Century" (PDF). Archived (PDF) from the original on 17 December 2008. Retrieved 30 December 2008.
  39. ^ Jones, G. Gareth (1977). "The British Government and the Oil Companies 1912–1924: The Search for an Oil Policy". The Historical Journal. 2 (3): 647–672. doi:10.1017/s0018246x00011286. JSTOR 2638433. S2CID 161977401.
  40. ^ (Croce-Einaudi, 1988, p. 139)
  41. ^ Giovanni Sartori. The Theory of Democracy Revisited (1987). Chatham, New Jersey. Chatham House. ISBN 0-934540-49-7.
  42. ^ a b Pietro Moroni (25 April 2015). "Le due facce della medaglia neoliberale – Pandora Rivista". Pandora Rivista. Archived from the original on 22 June 2018. Retrieved 22 October 2018.
  43. ^ Croce ed Einaudi: un confronto su liberalismo e liberismo entry (in Italian) in the Enciclopedia italiana
  44. ^ Dario Antiseri. Liberalismo politico e liberalismo economico. Rubettino.
  45. ^ F.Hayek (1997). Liberalismo. Ideazione. p. 62. Ciò comporta anche il rifiuto della distinzione tra liberalismo politico e liberalismo economico /elaborata in particolare da Croce come distinzione tra liberismo e liberalismo) Per la tradizione inglese, i due concetti sono inseparabili. Infatti, il principio fondamentale per cui l'intervento coercitivo dell'autorità statale deve limitarsi ad imporre il rispetto delle norme generali di mera condotta priva il governo del potere di dirigere e controllare le attività economiche degli individui.
  46. ^ I sostenitori dell'esistenza di una dottrina liberista la attribuiscono ad Adam Smith e al suo saggio La Ricchezza delle Nazioni, laddove questi utilizzò il termine "liberal policy" un paio di volte per indicare il commercio privo di dazi. Smith non vedeva di buon occhio l'assenza di regolamentazione statale, infatti dichiarò: «Raramente la gente dello stesso mestiere si ritrova insieme, anche se per motivi di svago e di divertimento, senza che la conversazione risulti in una cospirazione contro i profani o in un qualche espediente per far alzare i prezzi».
  47. ^ La lingua francese parla di libéralisme politique e libéralisme économique (quest'ultimo chiamato anche laissez-faire, lett. lasciate fare), lo spagnolo di liberalismo social e liberalismo económico. La lingua inglese parla di free trade (libero commercio) ma usa il termine liberalism anche per riferirsi al liberismo economico.
  48. ^ Carlo, Scogniamiglio Pasini. "Liberismo e liberalismo nella polemica fra Croce ed Einaudi" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 28 December 2016. Retrieved 22 October 2018.
  49. ^ Boehm-Bawerk (1999). Potere o legge economica?. Rubbettino. p. 67.
  50. ^ Bourgin, Frank (1989). The Great Challenge: The Myth of Laissez-Faire in the Early Republic. New York: George Braziller Inc. ISBN 978-0-06-097296-7.[page needed]
  51. ^ Bourgin, Frank (1 June 1989). "The Great Challenge: The Myth of Laissez-faire in the Early Republic". Kirkusreviews.com. Archived from the original on 21 September 2013. Retrieved 30 July 2013.
  52. ^ Prince, Carl E.; Taylor, Seth (1982). "Daniel Webster, the Boston Associates, and the U.S. Government's Role in the Industrializing Process, 1815–1830". Journal of the Early Republic. 2 (3): 283–299. doi:10.2307/3122975. JSTOR 3122975.
  53. ^ a b Guelzo, Allen C. (1999). Abraham Lincoln: Redeemer President. Grand Rapids: W.B. Eerdmans Pub. Co. ISBN 978-0-8028-3872-8.[page needed]
  54. ^ "From Sea to Shining Sea: The Heroes and Villains of the First Transcontinental Railroad". The Objective Standard. 2019-05-10. Archived from the original on 2021-04-29. Retrieved 2021-04-29.
  55. ^ Robert W. Crandall (1987). "The Effects of U.S. Trade Protection for Autos and Steel" (PDF). Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 1987 (1): 271–288. doi:10.2307/2534518. JSTOR 2534518. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2019-10-01. Retrieved 2019-09-24.
  56. ^ Pietro S. Nivola (1986). "The New Protectionism: U.S. Trade Policy in Historical Perspective". Political Science Quarterly. 101 (4): 577–600. doi:10.2307/2150795. JSTOR 2150795.
  57. ^ Rand, Ayn Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal, Ch. 7, New American Library, Signet, 1967.
  58. ^ Armstrong, J. Scott; Green, Kesten C. (2013-10-01). "Effects of corporate social responsibility and irresponsibility policies". Journal of Business Research. Strategic Thinking in Marketing. 66 (10): 1922–1927. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.663.508. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.02.014. S2CID 145059055.
  59. ^ Peikoff 1991, pp. 350–352.
  60. ^ Gotthelf 2000, pp. 91–92; Peikoff 1991, pp. 379–380.
  61. ^ Peikoff 1991, pp. 369.
  62. ^ Peikoff 1991, p. 367.
  63. ^ Burns 2009, pp. 174–177, 209, 230–231; Den Uyl & Rasmussen 1986, pp. 225–226; Doherty 2007, pp. 189–190; Branden 1986, p. 252.
  64. ^ Sciabarra 1995, pp. 266–267; Burns 2009, pp. 268–269.
  65. ^ Sciabarra 1995, pp. 280–281; Peikoff 1991, pp. 371–372; Merrill 1991, p. 139.
  66. ^ Nolan, Peter (2008). Capitalism and Freedom: The Contradictory Character of Globalisation. Anthem Press. ISBN 978-1-84331-282-6. Retrieved 9 February 2017.
  67. ^ Orchard, Lionel; Stretton, Hugh (2016). Public Goods, Public Enterprise, Public Choice: Theoretical Foundations of the Contemporary Attack on Government. Springer. ISBN 978-1-349-23505-6. Retrieved 9 February 2017.
  68. ^ Milton Friedman on Labor Unions – Free To Choose, archived from the original on 2021-12-11, retrieved 2021-04-29
  69. ^ "Economics vs. 'Need', by Dr. Thomas Sowell". www.creators.com. 2013-06-11. Archived from the original on 2021-04-29. Retrieved 2021-04-29.
  70. ^ Paris, Jeffrey (1 July 2005). "Rethinking the End of Modernity". Social Philosophy Today. 21: 173–189. doi:10.5840/socphiltoday20052120.
  71. ^ Kilgore, Christopher D. (2017). "Bad Networks: From Virus to Cancer in Post-Cyberpunk Narrative". Journal of Modern Literature. 40 (2): 165–183. doi:10.2979/jmodelite.40.2.10. JSTOR 10.2979/jmodelite.40.2.10. S2CID 157670471.
  72. ^ Nick Manley. "Brief Introduction To Left-Wing Laissez Faire Economic Theory: Part One" Archived 2021-08-18 at the Wayback Machine.
  73. ^ Nick Maley. "Brief Introduction To Left-Wing Laissez Faire Economic Theory: Part Two". Archived 2021-05-16 at the Wayback Machine
  74. ^ Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty. Brooklyn, NY:Minor Compositions/Autonomedia
  75. ^ "It introduces an eye-opening approach to radical social thought, rooted equally in libertarian socialism and market anarchism." Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia. p. back cover.
  76. ^ "But there has always been a market-oriented strand of libertarian socialism that emphasizes voluntary cooperation between producers. And markets, properly understood, have always been about cooperation. As a commenter at Reason magazine's Hit&Run blog, remarking on Jesse Walker's link to the Kelly article, put it: "every trade is a cooperative act." In fact, it's a fairly common observation among market anarchists that genuinely free markets have the most legitimate claim to the label "socialism."" "Socialism: A Perfectly Good Word Rehabilitated" Archived 2016-03-10 at the Wayback Machine by Kevin Carson at website of Center for a Stateless Society.
  77. ^ Tucker, Benjamin. "State Socialism and Anarchism" Archived 2019-03-11 at the Wayback Machine.
  78. ^ Brown, Susan Love. 1997. "The Free Market as Salvation from Government". In Meanings of the Market: The Free Market in Western Culture. Berg Publishers. p. 107.
  79. ^ Carson, Kevin A. (2008). Organization Theory: A Libertarian Perspective. Charleston, SC:BookSurge.
  80. ^ Carson, Kevin A. (2010). The Homebrew Industrial Revolution: A Low-Overhead Manifesto. Charleston, SC: BookSurge.
  81. ^ Long, Roderick T. (2000). Reason and Value: Aristotle versus Rand. Washington, DC:Objectivist Center
  82. ^ Long, Roderick T. (2008). "An Interview With Roderick Long Archived 2020-03-27 at the Wayback Machine"
  83. ^ Johnson, Charles W. (2008). "Liberty, Equality, Solidarity: Toward a Dialectical Anarchism Archived 2022-06-26 at the Wayback Machine." Anarchism/Minarchism: Is a Government Part of a Free Country? In Long, Roderick T. and Machan, Tibor Aldershot: Ashgate pp. 155–188.
  84. ^ Spangler, Brad (15 September 2006). "Market Anarchism as Stigmergic Socialism Archived 10 May 2011 at archive.today.
  85. ^ Richman, Sheldon (23 June 2010). "Why Left-Libertarian? Archived 2020-01-03 at the Wayback Machine" The Freeman. Foundation for Economic Education.
  86. ^ Richman, Sheldon (18 December 2009). "Workers of the World Unite for a Free Market". Archived 22 July 2014 at the Wayback Machine." Foundation for Economic Education.
  87. ^ a b Sheldon Richman (3 February 2011). "Libertarian Left: Free-market anti-capitalism, the unknown ideal Archived 9 May 2012 at the Wayback Machine." The American Conservative. Retrieved 5 March 2012.
  88. ^ Sciabarra, Chris Matthew (2000). Total Freedom: Toward a Dialectical Libertarianism. University Park, PA:Pennsylvania State University Press.
  89. ^ Chartier, Gary (2009). Economic Justice and Natural Law. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.
  90. ^ Gillis, William (2011). "The Freed Market." In Chartier, Gary and Johnson, Charles. Markets Not Capitalism. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia. pp. 19–20.
  91. ^ Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia. pp. 1–16.
  92. ^ Gary Chartier and Charles W. Johnson (eds). Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty. Minor Compositions; 1st edition (November 5, 2011
  93. ^ Gary Chartier has joined Kevin Carson, Charles W. Johnson and others (echoing the language of Benjamin Tucker, Lysander Spooner and Thomas Hodgskin) in maintaining that—because of its heritage, emancipatory goals and potential—radical market anarchism should be seen by its proponents and by others as part of the socialist tradition and that market anarchists can and should call themselves socialists. See Gary Chartier, "Advocates of Freed Markets Should Oppose Capitalism," "Free-Market Anti-Capitalism?" session, annual conference, Association of Private Enterprise Education (Cæsar's Palace, Las Vegas, NV, April 13, 2010); Gary Chartier, "Advocates of Freed Markets Should Embrace 'Anti-Capitalism'" Archived 2019-09-29 at the Wayback Machine; Gary Chartier, Socialist Ends, Market Means: Five Essays Archived 2019-03-28 at the Wayback Machine . Cp. Tucker, "Socialism."
  94. ^ Nick Manley, "Brief Introduction To Left-Wing Laissez Faire Economic Theory: Part One" Archived 2021-08-18 at the Wayback Machine.
  95. ^ Nick Manley, "Brief Introduction To Left-Wing Laissez Faire Economic Theory: Part Two" Archived 2021-05-16 at the Wayback Machine.
  96. ^ "Introductions – Kevin Carson" Archived 2019-03-29 at the Wayback Machine.
  97. ^ Carson, Kevin. "Intellectual Property – A Libertarian Critique". c4ss.org. Archived from the original on September 11, 2012. Retrieved May 23, 2009.
  98. ^ Kevin A. Carson, Introduction Archived 2012-10-16 at the Wayback Machine, The Art of the Possible.
  99. ^ Carson, Kevin. "Industrial Policy: New Wine in Old Bottles". c4ss.org. Archived from the original on September 11, 2012. Retrieved May 26, 2009.
  100. ^ Kevin Carson, "Studies in Mutualist Political Economy", Archived 15 April 2011 at the Wayback Machine chs. 1–3.
  101. ^ Carson, Kevin A. Carson's Rejoinders Archived 2014-08-17 at the Wayback Machine. Journal of Libertarian Studies, Volume 20, No. 1 (Winter 2006): 97–136 [116–117].
  102. ^ a b Richman, Sheldon, Libertarian Left Archived 14 August 2011 at the Wayback Machine, The American Conservative (March 2011).
  103. ^ Dean, Brian (Winter 2002). "Bluffer's Guide to Revolutionary Economics". The Idler. Archived from the original on 27 April 2009. Retrieved 24 May 2009.
  104. ^ Marx, Theories of Surplus Value, III, p. 501.
  105. ^ See Gary Chartier, Anarchy and Legal Order: Law and Politics for a Stateless Society (New York: Cambridge UP 2013) 44–156.
  106. ^ See Gary Chartier, "Natural Law and Non-Aggression," Acta Juridica Hungarica 51.2 (June 2010): 79–96 and, for an earlier version, Justice 32–46.
  107. ^ See Justice 47–68.
  108. ^ Justice 89–120.
  109. ^ See Gary Chartier, "Pirate Constitutions and Workplace Democracy," Jahrbuch für Recht und Ethik 18 (2010): 449–467.
  110. ^ Justice 123–154.
  111. ^ See Gary Chartier,' "Intellectual Property and Natural Law," Australian Journal of Legal Philosophy 36 (2011): 58–88.
  112. ^ See Justice 176–182.
  113. ^ "Advocates of Freed Markets Should Embrace "Anti-Capitalism" Archived 2021-10-23 at the Wayback Machine.
  114. ^ a b c d Spencer J. Pack. Capitalism as a Moral System: Adam Smith's Critique of the Free Market Economy. Great Britain: Edward Elgar, 2010. Print
  115. ^ Macfie, A.L. (1959). "Adam Smith's Moral Sentiments as Foundation for His Wealth of Nations". Oxford Economic Papers. 11 (3): 209–228. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a040824.
  116. ^ Hobbes, Thomas (1909–14). Of Man, Being the First Part of Leviathan. Collier & Son.
  117. ^ "Enlightenment". History.com. 2009. Archived from the original on 2021-02-07. Retrieved 2021-04-29.
  118. ^ McNally, David (1993). Against the Market: Political Economy, Market Socialism and the Marxist Critique. Verso. ISBN 978-0-86091-606-2.
  119. ^ Dostaler, Gilles, Keynes and His Battles (Edward Elgar Publishing, 2007), p. 91.
  120. ^ Dostaler 2007, p. 91; Barnett, Vincent, John Maynard Keynes (Routledge, 2013), p. 143.
  121. ^ White, Lawrence H. (1999). "Why Didn't Hayek Favor Laissez Faire in Banking?" (PDF). History of Political Economy. 31 (4): 753–769. doi:10.1215/00182702-31-4-753. Archived (PDF) from the original on 1 April 2013. Retrieved 11 April 2013.
  122. ^ Polanyi, Karl (1944). The Great Transformation. Farrar & Rinehart.
  123. ^ McCloskey, Deirdre (1997). "Polanyi Was Right, and Wrong" (PDF). Eastern Economic Journal. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2021-08-07. Retrieved 2021-07-26.
  124. ^ Kuttner, Robert (19 December 2001). "Globalization and Its Critics". The American Prospect. Archived from the original on 13 September 2018. Retrieved 17 March 2019.
  125. ^ Kerckhove, Gilbert Van (2012). Toxic Capitalism: The Orgy of Consumerism and Waste: Are We the Last Generation on Earth?. AuthorHouse. ISBN 978-1-4772-1906-5. Retrieved 9 February 2017.
  126. ^ "Müntefering's criticism of raw capitalism strikes a chord". Financial Times. Archived from the original on 2022-12-10. Retrieved 9 February 2017.[permanent dead link]

Sources[edit]

Further reading[edit]

External links[edit]

Listen to this article (1 minute)
Spoken Wikipedia icon
This audio file was created from a revision of this article dated 27 June 2008 (2008-06-27), and does not reflect subsequent edits.