Free trade unions (Germany)

from Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Postcard about the fight for the eight-hour day (published by Richard Lipinski approx. 1901–1910)

In Germany, free trade unions are the socialist- oriented trade union organizations of the 19th and 20th centuries. The term "free" is an addition that has emerged over time to distinguish the organizations from the competing liberal Hirsch-Duncker trade unions on the one hand and the Christian trade unions on the other. In Austria , too , the socialist organizations were called free trade unions for the same reason .

After precursors, socialist or social democratically oriented unions have developed since the 1860s, both in the environment of the General German Workers 'Association (ADAV), which is actually trade union skeptical, and the Social Democratic Workers' Party (SDAP). The two directions united in 1875. The Socialist Law of 1878 marked a deep break that set back development . A new structure took place while the law was still in force. But only after its abolition in 1890 could the free trade unions develop into a mass organization. The previous individual organizations merged in 1890 to form the General Commission of the German Trade Unions . The free trade unions developed to the largest membership union direction . Within the social democratic labor movement they formed a basis for a reforming wing. In 1906 the trade unions enforced equality between the party and the trade unions against the SPD .

During the First World War they supported the government's civil peace policy . With the Auxiliary Services Act , the unions were recognized by the state as professional representatives of the workers' interests. Shortly after the beginning of the November Revolution, they agreed the Stinnes-Legien Agreement with employers, which also earned them recognition of employers as negotiating partners.

At the beginning of the Weimar Republic , the organization of free trade unions was renamed General German Trade Union Federation . Before the First World War, the General Commission helped to organize the (few) social democratic-oriented employees, but in 1920 the General Free Employees' Association (AfA-Bund) was founded. In 1924 the General German Association of Officials (ADB) was founded. Both this organization of civil servants and the AfA-Bund were loosely connected to the ADGB. One spoke at the time of the "three-pillar model" of the workers' movement.

The free trade unions reached their peak in importance in the early 1920s. During this time they reached their highest membership numbers. The general strike of the trade unions contributed significantly to the suppression of the Kapp putsch . During the period of inflation , the organization fell into a deep crisis. After a phase of recovery, the global economic crisis was linked to another weakening of the free trade unions. In the early days of National Socialist rule , the leaders of the free trade unions tried to keep the organization alive and adapted to the new regime. This did not prevent the free trade unions from being smashed immediately after “National Labor Day” ( May 1st ) 1933.

Early days

Sample number of the magazine "Das Volk" published by Stephan Born

The first union-like approaches already existed in the pre-March period . The Gutenberg Association was founded in 1846 by Leipzig book printers . The printer was an important group of the early labor movement later on. They could look back on an old organizational tradition. In 1848, principals and journeymen founded a joint national book printer association before, after labor disputes, an organization of journeymen was formed with the Gutenbergbund in 1849. Stephan Born , who came into contact with Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels in Paris and became a member of the League of Communists , also emerged from the printing environment .

The second group that organized nationally at a particularly early stage were the cigar workers. During the revolution of 1848 the first cigar workers' congress took place on September 25, 1848, at which a central organization was founded with the Association of Cigar Workers in Germany . In some cases, it was still based on the professional policy of the guilds. In addition, minimum wages and collective agreements have already been demanded. In 1849, 77 locations were represented in this association. The organizations were able to build on existing support and educational associations.

While the League of Communists, with its main focus on the Rhineland , took care of programmatic issues during the revolution, the General German Workers' Brotherhood founded by Stephan Born in Berlin became the real origin of the organized labor movement. Even if masters were still organized in it, it made demands to improve the situation of the workers. These included, for example, minimum wages and a regulation of working hours, but also the demand for freedom of association . These and other points were later also among the important demands of the trade union workers' movement.

Organized by Born among others, a general workers' congress took place in Berlin . In the appeal in Born's magazine Das Volk it was said:

"Let us unite, who up to now have been weak and unconsidered in terms of isolation and fragmentation. We count millions and form the great majority of the nation. Only united in equal striving will we be strong and attain that power which is due to us as the producers of all wealth. Our voice is a heavy one and we will not fail to put it on the scales of social democracy. "

Ultimately, the various approaches to the emergence of a labor movement in the reaction era could not hold up. In 1850, the printers and tobacco workers union and the workers' fraternity were banned.

However, there were still labor disputes at the local level, partly linked to organizations from the revolutionary era . In 1850 around 2,000 cloth workers went on strike in Lennep . There had been a workers' association there during the revolution, which had broadcast to other places in the Bergisches Land . Before the strike, a new club could be established in Lennep. The movement was suppressed militarily. Labor disputes in Elberfeld and Barmen in 1855 and 1857 were similar . In general, the strike has gradually established itself as a method of enforcing material interests during this period. In 1857 alone there were 41 strikes. The police did not succeed in banning all mergers. At the local level, some organizations continued to exist or were newly formed as support funds or educational and social associations.

Development up to the end of the socialist law

Requirements for forming a union

Alongside the book printers, the cigar workers were a core group of the early trade union movement (painting by J. Marx from 1889)

In Prussia in the 1860s, during the so-called New Era, the conditions for workers' organizational aspirations improved . In the time of the constitutional conflict, left liberalism and the bourgeois democrats wooed the workers. From this environment, the labor movement was strongly promoted, especially in the form of workers' education associations. It is estimated that between 1860 and 1864 225 workers' and craftsmen's associations were established.

Gradually, however, there were efforts to develop independent organizations independent of the bourgeoisie. As such, the General German Workers' Association (ADAV) was established in 1863 . In addition, the Association of German Workers' Associations (VDAV) came into being, initially still associated with left-wing liberalism . In 1868 August Bebel and Karl Liebknecht transformed it into a workers' organization. During this time, the labor movement was divided into two parts: party and union. The party prevailed in Germany until the end of the 19th century. In Britain, on the other hand, unions had become powerful organizations long before the Labor Party was formed around the turn of the century . In Germany it was the other way around. First, workers' parties emerged, and only then were unions dependent on them. The party liked to view the unions as secondary schools for their offspring.

An important prerequisite for the creation of permanent trade union organizations had the right of association . In Prussia there had been a legal ban on coalitions since 1845, which was tightened in 1854. In 1860 state control over employment relationships in the mining industry finally ended. The coalition ban was expressly anchored in the mining law of 1865. Not only in working-class circles, but also among social reformers like Gustav Schmoller , the coalition ban was viewed increasingly critically. In particular from left-wing liberal circles there were attacks against the ban on mergers. In the Kingdom of Saxony , the ban on coalitions fell in 1861, when Prussia began to adopt a more relaxed approach in 1867, before the trade regulations of the North German Confederation in 1869 expressly granted the right of association.

The time when socialist trade unions were formed

August Bebel drafted model statutes for the international trade unions
Despite theoretical concerns, Johann Baptist von Schweitzer founded the workforce in the ADAV environment

While Axel Kuhn is of the opinion that the unions were founded by the parties, Klaus Schönhoven emphasizes that the original impulses for the establishment of a union did not come from the parties, but that they developed autonomously. Both ADAV and VDAV took up these efforts hesitantly at first in order to strengthen their base. The establishment of trade unions by the ADAV actually contradicted the wage law as a central component of the party ideology. This means that wage increases achieved through strikes or similar measures would immediately be canceled out by the market. A union with the aim of pushing through wage increases would therefore make no sense. The party argued that unions were useful in raising awareness and therefore useful. The consequences of the parties' engagement were ambivalent. On the one hand, they accelerated the process of mobilization, on the other hand, the unions got caught up in political conflicts.

As in 1848, the cigar workers and book printers started with the establishment of central associations. The cigar workers founded an association in 1865 under the direction of Friedrich Wilhelm Fritzsche . The book printers had already founded a Central German Book Printers Association in 1863. The so-called threepenny strike in Leipzig triggered a Germany-wide wave of solidarity and the inflow of numerous donations from other industries. The strike defeat increased the urge to unite across Germany. At the first Buchdruckertag in Leipzig in 1866, 84 local associations with around 3000 members were represented. Richard Härtel took over the management of the printing movement in 1867 , and in 1868 an umbrella organization of regional district associations was founded. The Association of German Book Printers was more closely related to the VDAV, but initially stayed out of party-political conflicts. In 1869 it had about 6,000 members in 426 locations, which were organized in 41 district associations. The General German Tailors' Association was also one of the early central associations. He was also close to the ADAV and in 1869 had around 3,000 members. The early organizations consisted primarily of qualified and mostly skilled workers in small to medium-sized companies. They were mostly younger men between 20 and 30 years of age. Older people and women initially played no role.

The breakthrough of the trade union movement took place in 1868. The long-lasting good economic situation of the early days played an important role. The workers also wanted to benefit from the growing prosperity. In the VDAV, Bebel and Liebknecht had largely prevailed and established the connection to the International Workers' Association . Following the Association Day in Nuremberg in 1868, Bebel called for the establishment of international trade unions . At the same time, Bebel published a model statute. This envisaged a democratic structure from the bottom up. The establishment took place from the local cooperatives through the district associations to the central board. Particularly at the beginning, some organizations followed the “on-site principle.” One place temporarily became the seat of the association and the local board acted as the board for the overall organization. Annual general assemblies were held at which the management board and a supervisory body ( control commission ) were elected. In principle, this type of structure is still valid today. In the fall of 1869 the membership should have been around 15,000. In the meantime, the Social Democratic Workers' Party had also been founded, to which the trade unions can be assigned. However, there was still no umbrella organization.

Johann Baptist von Schweitzer as the new ADAV President feared that the formation of a union by the VDAV would reduce the attraction of the ADAV. In great haste he convened a General German Workers' Congress in Berlin in September 1868 to found his own trade unions. He acted deliberately against the Lassallean dogma and accepted the splitting off of an orthodox wing around Fritz Mende and Countess Hatzfeld . In fact, nine of the twelve planned workers for various professions and industries were established at the congress .

As a result, there was criticism of the unions within the party, which contributed to the decline of the organization. On the other hand, the displeasure about a lack of internal democracy caused some associations to switch to the camp of the trade unions. In 1870 the workers 'unions were then merged into the workers' support association. The abandonment of the professional principle in favor of a unitary association met with resistance. At the beginning of the 1870s the labor force still had around 21,000 members. In 1871 there were just 4,200 members.

Incidentally, the left-liberal Hirsch-Duncker trade unions with around 16,000 members were founded in 1868 in mid-1869. However, the left-liberal trade unions found little support in the ranks of the Progress Party . In the Catholic camp, Christian social workers' associations emerged in the Rhenish-Westphalian region, which at this time also pursued union-political goals. In the 1880s, what was left was absorbed by the Catholic workers' associations, which were no longer unionized . In this respect, it was already becoming apparent at this point in time that there was a split into unions .

Unions in the early days

The strike (painting by Robert Koehler , 1886)

Theodor York could not prevail with his idea of ​​a party-political neutrality of the trade union movement, although it was advocated by the leading trade union theorist Carl Hillmann at the time . York also unsuccessfully proposed a union of the various professional unions so that the financially weak organizations could support each other if necessary. This was also a reaction to the stagnating development of the organizations after the establishment of the empire. In Berlin, localist competition developed with the Berlin Workers' Union . The new ADAV President Carl Wilhelm Tölcke even wanted to dissolve the unions again, but was unable to fully assert himself in his own ranks. Another problem was that numerous union members had to do military service in the Franco-German War . This weakened financial strength, and national enthusiasm weakened approval of all social democratic organizations. Four out of ten trade unions did not survive 1870.

Despite this organizational stagnation, there were numerous strikes in the early years due to the good economic situation. On Waldburger miners' strike in 1869/70 to about 7,000 workers took part. In 1872 there were at least 362 strikes with around 100,000 participants. In the spring of 1873, for example, the printers fought over a collective agreement. The strikes in the construction sector were particularly numerous. A miners' strike broke out in the Ruhr area in 1872 . Ultimately, 21,000 miners were involved in this, and it is considered the first mass strike in German history. The attempt to subsequently found a union failed, not least because of resistance from employers and the state. Incidentally, the strike wave around 1872 was not limited to Germany; there were also a number of labor disputes in other countries. Numerous industries were involved in Germany. Apart from the big cities, Prussia, Saxony and northern Bavaria in particular were affected by it. These strikes gave a boost to the development of the unions as a whole.

Regional focal points of the early unions were central Germany , the Rhenish-Westphalian industrial area , as well as large cities such as Leipzig , Berlin, Hanover and Hamburg . The total number of union members is estimated to be around 60,000 to 70,000 in 1870-71. This would correspond to an organization level of 2 to 3 percent.

Tessendorf era and striving for unification

Theodor Yorck was an important figure in the early trade union movement

In 1874 the start-up crisis followed the start-up boom . It was not until the 1890s that a longer period of boom set in again. In some cases, labor incomes fell dramatically, and the weak economy greatly reduced the chances of success in labor disputes. Overall, the entrepreneur's ability to assert himself increased. This was at least partially supported by politics under Otto von Bismarck . In 1873 he submitted the so-called breach of contract draft as a supplement to the Reichsgewerbeordnung , which restricted the right of association. However, the bill also failed in the Reichstag due to the resistance of the National Liberals . In the Tessendorf era, named after the public prosecutor Hermann Tessendorf , the persecution of workers' organizations began in 1874, especially in Prussia, but also in other federal states.

From the workers 'point of view, given the increased employers' power and state repression, the Marxist interpretation of the class state and class struggle seemed increasingly plausible. Marxism prevailed as an ideology until 1890. The experience of state persecution in the 1870s / 80s left a lasting mark on at least one generation of workers' leaders. It also resulted in the party and trade unions becoming even closer to one another. The idea that the trade unions are subordinate to the party solidified.

The growing state pressure also led to the unification of the two workers 'parties to form the Socialist Workers' Party of Germany (SAP) in 1875 and thus to an end to the conflicts between the two camps. In the longer term, the ADAV's anti-union stance lost weight in the new party. A trade union conference was also held there after the Gotha unification convention in 1875. It was decided that they wanted to keep politics out of the unions. The actual unification of the associations took longer than expected, but was ultimately successful.

Centralization made less progress overall. The fact that Theodor Yorck, the real engine of centralization, died in 1875 also played a role. These efforts were carried on by August Geib and others. Various attempts were made to found an umbrella organization, but several congresses could not take place for various reasons.

Organizational structure around 1878

Statistics compiled by August Geib in 1877/78 give an insight into the structure of the social democratically oriented trade unions before the Socialist Law. The strongest organization with 8100 members was that of the tobacco workers. This was followed by book printers (5500), joiners (5100), metal workers (3555), shoemakers (3585), carpenters (3300), ship carpenters (3000), tailors (2800), hat makers (2767), bricklayers (2500) and factory workers (1800 ). There were also a number of smaller associations with fewer than 1,000 members. Geib had a total of around 50,000 members. For the year 1878 one assumes an increase to 60,000 members. The craftsmen dominated . Until the end of the empire, the farm workers could not be organized . In mining there was only a stable association in Saxony. In the Ruhr region , there were Christian social aspirations, but failed 1878th The success of the textile workers and the less qualified factory workers was relatively low. The manual trades dominated the metalworkers. The number of employees in heavy industry was significantly lower . Overall, the structure has hardly changed compared to the early years of the trade unions. The unions were organized according to the club model, company organizations basically played no role. This was also one of the reasons why syndicalism only played a minor role in Germany.

Under the socialist law

Reichsgesetzblatt with the law against the endangering efforts of the social democracy
Call to the meeting

The free trade unions were also severely affected by the Socialist Law , which was directed against all social democratic, socialist or communist associations. Some unions, such as bricklayers, disbanded themselves to protect cash and other property from confiscation. Numerous trade unions and local professional associations were banned in 1878/79. The same was true of numerous union newspapers. The printer's association and the Hirsch-Duncker trade unions remained because of their non-social-democratic character. Other unions turned into support associations and some of them could continue to exist. According to an estimate by Ignaz Auer , 17 central associations, 78 local associations, 23 relief funds and a number of other associations were banned while the Socialist Act was in force. 1299 printed matter were also affected by the law. A total of 831 years' imprisonment was imposed and 893 people were evicted from their homes.

During the years of the Socialist Law, some important structural changes took place. Although the economic slump of the start-up crisis was not completely over, industrial development continued during the period of high industrialization in Germany . Between 1875 and 1890, the number of people employed in the mining and manufacturing industries increased by 30%. After all, more people worked in this area than in agriculture. The introduction of important components of the Bismarck social security system also fell during this period .

In 1879 and 1880 the union movement was largely eliminated. Some active trade unionists preferred emigration to reprisals. Since 1881 the socialist law was then applied less rigorously. A few professional associations began to form, mostly at the local level. In addition, Christian social endeavors intensified.

Central support organizations gradually emerged from local associations. By the end of 1884 there were again thirteen central associations. In 1888 there were a total of 40 associations. On the basis of these associations and local clubs, the trade union movement in 1885 had a similarly high number of members as before the Socialist Act. A total of 775,000 workers belonged to the relief funds in 1885.

As long as there was a purely union effort, this development was tolerated by the authorities. If there were links to the illegal party, that was over. In view of the increasing strike activity, the authorities tightened the course again in 1886. Interior Minister Robert von Puttkamer issued the so-called strike decree. New bans were issued, which particularly concerned the organizational efforts of metal workers and in the construction sector. Nevertheless, there were other foundings. According to official figures, the number of union members in 1888 was 110,000. In 1890 there were 295,000. The largest part belonged to the free trade unions. The Hirsch-Duncker trade associations had up to 63,000 members during this time.

The big strikes in 1889 also made it clear that the socialist law had not succeeded in suppressing the labor movement. The best known is the strike in the Ruhr mining industry , in which 90,000 out of 104,000 miners were involved. An organization of miners also emerged from the strike . The strike also boosted union organization as a whole. In 1890 the socialist law expired. This marked the beginning of a new phase in union development.

Rise to the mass movement

Basic conditions

An essential prerequisite for the boom in trade unionism as a whole was the boom since the 1890s. This continued with economic interruptions until 1914. The Hirsch-Duncker trade unions also benefited from this, and independent Christian trade unions developed from 1894 onwards . During this time, the system of directional trade unions was formed, which was to last until 1933.

Large strikes like the miners 'strike in 1889 in the Ruhr area or the strike in Hamburg in 1890 showed how great the need was to represent workers' interests. The defeat in the Hamburg May fights also showed how little fragmented organizations could do against employers. Individual groups of workers and locally oriented organizations turned out to be too weak to successfully survive long and severe conflicts.

Professional or industrial association?

Martin Segitz was one of the co-initiators of the first nationwide trade union meeting

The clarification of the organizational question was of central importance for the free trade unions. Encouraged by representatives of the metal workers, in particular Martin Segitz from Nuremberg , calls for a nationwide meeting of free trade unions were loud. In November 1890, the participants of a free trade union conference in Berlin debated the future form of organization. There were representatives who stood up for professional associations. This applies, for example, to the book printer or tailor. But there were also advocates of cross-professional organizations as an industrial association. This included some metal workers. The result was a compromise. Professional associations continued to be accepted, but large, inter-professional organizations should also be able to emerge. Both sides could live with that. In the resolution passed in Berlin, the delegates spoke out in favor of organizations throughout the Reich and against local associations. With this, localism as a political and economic organization, which had a relatively large number of supporters, especially in Berlin, was rejected.

The metal workers united in 1891 to form the German Metal Workers' Association (DMV), a cross-professional industrial association. They were followed in 1893 by the German Woodworkers Association . Most of the other unions remained professional associations.

At a conference in Halberstadt in 1891, a majority of the delegates spoke out in favor of a loose association of related professions, without this being implemented in practice. At the Halberstadt Congress in 1892, after controversial debates, it was difficult to get beyond the Berlin resolutions. The professional association principle remained the central organizational basis. At least the professional associations were asked to conclude cartel agreements with each other for the various branches of industry, which did not take place. Congress confirmed the rejection of localism and emphasized the separation of political and trade union organization. This corresponded to the tendencies in the SPD. There, too, people turned against localism and advocated a separation of party and union. As a result, the localist associations were marginalized without having completely disappeared.

The focus on the professional association principle took into account the membership, which still consisted to a large extent of qualified journeyman workers and not yet of unskilled mass workers.

A point of contention within the trade unions was the question of whether, in addition to the payment of support for labor disputes, other support should also be paid in the event of unemployment, illness or disability. Opponents argued that it is not the job of the unions to take the social burden off the state or employers. Such cash registers could also limit performance in industrial disputes. The proponents said that one could bond the members more strongly through support funds. Ultimately, this opinion prevailed.

General Commission

Carl Legien was chairman of the general commission of the trade unions in Germany from 1890 to 1920

At the Berlin functionaries' conference, the general commission of the trade unions in Germany was also founded as an inter-association coordination and agitation body. The commission initially consisted of seven people. At first she was only active on a temporary basis and was mainly supposed to organize the upcoming congresses. Its members themselves saw the General Commission as a permanent institution from the start. Since 1891 she published the correspondence sheet. This became an important instrument in the internal union opinion-forming process. From the start, the leading figure in the commission was Carl Legien . He had already made a name for himself as a trade unionist in the professional wood turner's association in Hamburg since 1896. Last but not least, he succeeded in giving the General Commission its own weight against criticism, especially from the ranks of the metal workers.

At the Halberstadt Conference of 1891 he succeeded in obtaining permanent funding for the General Commission from the member associations. The Congress of 1892 confirmed the existence of the commission, but at the same time curtailed its powers. It should no longer be responsible for the financial support of defensive strikes. Above all, it should take care of professional groups where the degree of organization was still low. The General Commission kept statistics on the development of membership in the individual affiliated unions and on strike activity. It should also take care of developments in international relations. In a certain way, it was only a service provider bound by instructions for the member associations and not a management organization for the entire free trade unions.

Instead, Carl Legien wanted to transform the commission into a leading body in the long term. The Commission should not only encourage further trade union development, but also launch its own social policy initiatives. In 1894, for example, he initiated a workers' congress that was to deal with topics such as occupational safety, factory inspection, accident insurance and the right of assembly. This triggered a conflict between the trade unions and the SPD. This saw it as an intervention in their previous work area. The party saw its own leadership role in the social democratically oriented labor movement in danger. At this pressure Legien had to cancel the congress.

At the second trade union congress in 1896, the metalworkers' association fundamentally questioned the commission, but was unable to prevail. On the other hand, the Commission's attempt to set up a strike reserve fund managed by it failed. The attempt to bring the industrial action under the control of the General Commission had thus failed. These remained a matter for the individual unions. The commission was only allowed to collect strike money at the request of an individual union.

Nevertheless, the general approval of the General Commission gradually gained acceptance. At the Frankfurt trade union congress in 1899, the right to exist of the commission was undisputed. Congress passed an organizational statute for the commission. Her area of ​​responsibility has also been significantly expanded. So she was now also responsible for social policy issues. This indicated that the trade unions no longer wanted to subordinate themselves to the party, but gradually saw each other as equals.

Relationship between party and union

Development up to the turn of the century

Workers' demonstration on May 1st, 1900 in Stuttgart

The union-party relationship became a problem for a number of reasons. Although the trade union leaders were Social Democrats and Marxism had established itself as the dominant ideology, self-confidence in the unions had nonetheless grown. Its own rise in the 1880s contributed to this. It was not the party that supported the trade unions during this period, rather it was often the other way around. There was a new generation that had been socialized more in the trade union movement and less in the party.

In the party there was initially no reason to revise the theoretical understanding of the nature and tasks of the trade unions developed before 1870. In the Erfurt program of 1891 the leadership role of the party was again emphasized. The trade unionists accepted this without wanting to be content in the long run with the role of the trade unions as the party's recruiting school. Carl Legien wrote, for example, that the mass of workers could only be won over to the socialist idea through economic struggle "in today's bourgeois society" .

However, at this point he did not want to risk a conflict with the party, as the situation of the unions was critical. Various unions faced financial ruin after their strike defeats. The tobacco workers' union collapsed after being locked out . The miners' association lost numerous members when it left. This crisis of the trade unions confirmed in the SPD the conviction that only political struggle could point the way to socialism.

August Bebel sharply attacked the reformers in the trade unions. He himself hoped for the big "Kladderadatsch" of capitalist society soon and could not gain much from the reform efforts in the imperial state. However, the collapse of capitalism was a long time coming in the following years, while the organizing work of the unions was successful. It is characteristic of the party's distant relationship with the trade unions that no leading party politician attended trade union congresses until the turn of the century.

Equality of party and trade unions

The rapid growth of the trade union movement, the reformism of the trade union leaders, the emergence of revisionism in the SPD and the waning of workers' hopes for revolution forced a clarification of the relationship between party and trade union. The balance of power had meanwhile shifted in favor of the unions. With its 1.6 million members, the free trade unions had a considerable organizational lead over the SPD, which had fewer than 400,000 members.

Rosa Luxemburg was one of the main opponents of the trade unions in the mass strike debate

The different positions became particularly clear in two debates between 1899 and 1906: the neutrality debate and the mass strike debate . The neutrality debate was triggered by some union leaders who, in view of the successes of the Christian unions, pleaded for a greater distance from the SPD. In May 1899, Bebel gave up the party's claim to leadership in a keynote speech, recognized the independence of the trade unions and pleaded for their party-political neutrality. However, he warned against a course away from the SPD. The party theorist Karl Kautsky wrote in a programmatic paper in 1900 on the relationship between the party and the trade unions:

“The political organizations of the proletariat will always comprise only a small elite ; Mass organizations can only form the unions. A social democratic party, whose core troops are not the trade unions, therefore built on sand. The unions must remain outside the party. "

That also dictates

“The consideration of the special tasks of this organization. But social democracy always has to endeavor to ensure that the members of the trade union organizations are filled with a socialist spirit. The socialist propaganda among the unions has to go hand in hand with the propaganda for the unions in the party organization. "

The mass strike debate was about whether the general strike should also be used in deep political conflicts. Especially after the Russian Revolution of 1905 , this topic was on the agenda of the party and trade unions. The leading trade unionists opposed the mass strike because this strategy would have jeopardized the organization and the social advances made by the reform course. The 1905 trade union day in Cologne then rejected the mass strike with a large majority and opposed the syndicalists and the left wing in the SPD. This resolution not only triggered a corresponding backlash from Rosa Luxemburg and other supporters of the mass strike, criticism also came from within.

At the SPD party congress in Jena that same year, Bebel looked for a compromise, but rekindled the debate with his sentence that the mass strike was the “most effective means of combat”. As a result, the party and the trade unions appeared to be on the verge of a break. At the Mannheim party congress of 1906, the so-called Mannheim Agreement was reached : A compromise was found in the actual dispute. It was important that the SPD finally recognized the equality of the unions. It was also agreed to agree on a common course for actions affecting the interests of both sides. In practice this meant that the possibility of a mass strike was also off the table. The debate continued in the party, but it no longer played a significant role in relations with the trade unions.

structure

Development of the directional unions 1887–1912

Membership numbers

As a result of a temporarily faltering economy, the number of members of the free trade unions fell from around 300,000 in 1890 to 1895 by around 50,000. In the following years of economic boom, the number of members rose sharply to 680,427 in 1900. The Hirsch-Duncker trade unions had 90,000 members during this period and the Christian trade unions an estimated 76,000 members. In the following years the membership of the trade unions continued to grow. In 1913 the total was 3 million. A large part of around 2.5 million went to the free trade unions. The Christian trade unions had around 340,000 and the Hirsch-Duncker family 100,000 members.

The growth was closely related to the economic development. During the boom, the number of members increased particularly sharply, while it stagnated in economically weaker years. There were also other factors. Shortly before major labor disputes, membership increased. After the conflict ended, many left the organizations. Before the miners' strike in the Ruhr area in 1905, 60,000 workers joined the union. After the end of the strike, 30,000 left the organization. The fluctuations were a big problem for the organizations. Many new members were looking for the direct benefits of membership, but many were not interested in permanent commitment out of conviction or even in the general program. The uncertain income and living conditions also played a role. In the last few years before the start of the war, the trade unions responded to fluctuation by changing the statutes. Labor dispute support now depended on membership time.

Organizational promoting and inhibiting factors

Union houses like the one built in Nuremberg in 1907/08 testify to the self-confidence of the unions

Sectors, professions and regions differed in their degree of organization, because the respective organizational-promoting or inhibiting factors also differed significantly. As before, the level of organization was particularly high in some craft trades (book printer, coppersmith, glove maker and others). It was very difficult to organize workers in sectors with a high proportion of unskilled workers or women. This applied, for example, to the textile industry, trade or factory work.

There were areas in which the barriers for the unions were particularly high. In addition to the farm workers, these were the increasing numbers of employees in the public sector, for example in the railway or post office. Anti-union measures, restrictions on the right of association, but also special company social benefits prevented the unions from penetrating, especially those with a social democratic orientation. In the agricultural sector, the civil rights , the resistance of the landowners and the difficulty of finding access to the mentality of the rural population prevented the emergence of a noteworthy agricultural labor movement. In 1914, despite great agitation efforts, the agricultural workers' association had only 22,000 members. The free trade unions also had limited access to the growing number of employees . Most of the employees set themselves apart from the workers.

In key areas of industry such as heavy industry , anti-union measures and special company social benefits made it difficult for the unions to gain a foothold there. It was easier for trade unions in highly industrialized and urban areas than in rural areas. Berlin and Hamburg were therefore strongholds of the trade unions. They were relatively strong in central and northern Germany, but relatively weak in southern Germany and the eastern agricultural areas.

Inner structure

With regard to the individual trade unions, the organizations based on the industrial union principle were the most important. Of the 46 central associations of the free trade unions, the German Metalworkers' Association was by far the largest with over 500,000 members. The organizations in the construction, mining, wood and textile industries, the transport industry and the factory workers' association had over 100,000 members. This included very different areas of employment such as the chemical industry, rubber manufacturers or producers of margarine. Overall, the largest associations organized more than two thirds of all members of the free trade unions. The professional associations lagged far behind. These mostly organized individual craft trades. Despite their numerically insignificant size, they held on to their independence.

Against the background of the strong growth in membership but also the high fluctuation figures, the organization became increasingly professional. The number of full-time functionaries increased significantly. In 1898 there were only 104 paid functionaries in the free trade unions, there were already 2867 in 1914. These were mostly employed in the regional sub-divisions to look after the members. Increasingly, questions of labor law or collective bargaining policy required specialists. The tasks in the workers' secretariats , for example , became too complex to be carried out by volunteer officials alongside work. Most of the full-time functionaries themselves emerged from the workforce. Hence the growth of the full-time apparatus did not necessarily mean an alienation between the functionaries and the members.

However, the growth of the trade unions meant that members could no longer actively participate in all decision-making processes. A multi-level delegate system was set up and local decision-making autonomy was restricted. This is especially true for the strike decisions. These could initially still be taken at the local level. This changed in 1899 when a trade union congress assigned the power to strike to the central associations. For this purpose, special statutes were issued and the decision on industrial disputes was reserved to the central boards. This led to tensions in the associations without, however, leading to profound crises or even the disintegration of an organization. The board members did not always have their members completely under control. The shipyard workers' strike of 1913, which broke out against the will of the association, was particularly spectacular. One problem was the organization in local payment offices and the neglect of the company level.

Relations with politics and employers

Solidarity postcard with striking workers during the Crimmitschau strike

The political framework conditions were also important for the unions. After Leo von Caprivi's resignation , his conciliatory and social reform policy was given up, not least at the insistence of Wilhelm II . This relied on a policy of confrontation with the labor movement. The so-called prison bill that was launched in this context failed at the Reichstag in 1899. The anti-union policy was a failure. As a result, social legislation experienced numerous new impulses. Considerable progress has been made, among other things, with regard to occupational safety and the right of association. However, the state was far from recognizing the trade unions as the appointed representatives of the workers. The police still used force, for example during strikes. The full right of association was also not achieved. Employers were similarly negative. They fired well-known union members and blacklisted them .

Various developments in the economy hampered the further rise of the trade unions in the years before the First World War. Large-scale cartelized companies could hardly be wounded by strikes. In addition, strong employers' associations emerged. The Crimmitschau strike in 1903 turned into a confrontation between trade unions and employers beyond the local occasion. The strike led to a surge in the organization of employers. Only in a few areas, such as the wood and leather industry and the book printers, did the unions still have an organizational lead over employers before the war.

Especially in core economic areas such as mining, chemical, electrical and heavy industry, employers were superior to unions. In particular, the employers in mining and the coal and steel industry in the Ruhr area, Saarland and Rhineland often insisted on a “gentleman in the house”. Admittedly, this rigor was not so pronounced in other industries. Small and medium-sized company structures also made it easier for the unions to succeed in labor disputes.

The situation was also not clear in other respects. On the one hand, there are major mass strikes and lockouts that have attracted national attention, such as the lockout of construction workers in 1910, the miners 'strike in the Ruhr area of ​​1912 or the shipyard workers ' strike in the same year. On the other hand, there was a growing number of peaceful conflict solutions. The number of collective agreements increased sevenfold after 1905, even if employers were still able to set wages and working conditions for over four fifths of workers without the involvement of the trade unions. The extent to which the hardliners would have retained the upper hand in the heavy industrial companies in the long term must remain unclear, as the war has shifted the basic conditions.

The goal of legalizing labor relations, not unconditional confrontation with employers in labor disputes, was a characteristic of the German trade union movement. However, this course was not without controversy. The collective agreement for book printers in 1896 resulted in violent internal conflicts. The opponents saw in this a turning away from the class struggle . Ultimately, the opinion prevailed that collective bargaining agreements would improve the situation of workers without affecting the strike funds, which would preserve the fighting power of the organizations. In 1899 a trade union congress decided that the conclusion of collective agreements would be desirable.

First World War

Outbreak of war

Like the social democratic parties, the free trade unions also professed international solidarity. An international trade union confederation was created . Carl Legien was elected at the top. Like the parties of the Second International , in the July crisis of 1914 the appeals of the trade union international for the preservation of peace were unsuccessful. Instead, the internationality of the labor movement turned out to be an illusion.

The free trade unions signaled their support for the truce as early as August 2, thereby putting the SPD under pressure to act. The parliamentary group in the Reichstag, in which numerous active trade unionists were represented, approved the war credits on August 4th . The general mobilization of the Russian army played an important role in the decision. There was little doubt for those involved that Germany had to be defended against tsarism .

There were other reasons as well. This included the fear of dismantling the organization in the event of refusal. It was also hoped that the state would reward loyalty through concessions. On the right, however, there were also ideas of economic competition that were not dissimilar to the war goals of the government and the right.

The unions did not go on strikes for the duration of the war. Soon there were contacts with various military and civil authorities about nutrition issues, job creation or similar problems. The government relaxed police oversight of the unions and anti-union measures were less rigorous in state-owned companies. The interventions of the state in the economy were interpreted in the trade unions as the beginning of the turning away from capitalism and as a step towards socialism. It was overlooked that there was no clear objective behind this, but rather that it was mostly a reaction to certain predicaments. The hope of encouraging employers to expand the collective bargaining system initially met with limited success. Big industry in particular refused to accept the request. Only in some areas did the military authorities force employers and trade unions to set up war committees to remedy the shortage of skilled workers.

Inner conflicts

Hermann Jäckel was skeptical of the free trade unions' war policy

In political terms, the leading trade unionists emerged as resolute opponents of Karl Liebknecht's opponents in the SPD. Most of the trade unionists in the SPD parliamentary group belonged to an informal group of the right wing of the parliamentary group. They pleaded for tough action against the critics and consciously accepted the split between faction and party. But not all union members were behind them with this attitude. An appeal by the party opposition in 1915 was also signed by 150 union officials. At the Association Day of the DMV, the board's war course met with open criticism from the delegates. The General Commission stuck to its confrontational course against the left and put the party under pressure by threatening to found a trade union party if necessary.

The General Commission expressly welcomed the end of factional unity in 1916. With Hermann Jäckel from the textile workers' union and Josef Simon from the shoemakers there were also supporters of the opposition in the general commission, but both the opposition and the USPD wanted at least to keep the union unity. They hoped for a gradual strengthening of the opposition in the trade unions themselves. In fact, the opponents of the truce had already achieved a strong position in Berlin, Leipzig, Dresden or Braunschweig . On the Association Day of the DMV in 1917, the board was only just able to hold its own against the opposition. In the following years the position of the opposition in the DMV increased and in 1919 it was able to replace the old board.

Auxiliary Service Act

The highest army command around Hindenburg and Ludendorff sought to increase armaments production by introducing compulsory labor. Parties and unions forced concessions in the auxiliary service law

The unions themselves got into an organizational crisis after the start of the war. The number of members of the free trade unions sank to around the level of 1903 by 1916. The reasons were the drafting into the military, the initially high unemployment in non-war industries, but also the decline in attraction after the strike was abandoned. All of this resulted in a gradual loosening of union control over workers. Criticism of the truce policy of the union leaders also increased among union members. Wild strikes and food riots broke out since 1915 . The problematic war situation caused the Supreme Army Command under Hindenburg and Ludendorff to demand a comprehensive program to improve arms production. A major component was the restriction of freedom of movement and the obligation to work.

However, this required the approval of parliament and the trade unions. The unions agreed on a uniform approach and, based on the parties closely related to them, from the SPD to the left wing of the National Liberals, extensive changes were made to the Auxiliary Service Act . The unions agreed to the regulation of the labor market. In addition, workers 'and salaried employees' committees were set up in all war-important factories with more than 50 employees, the members of which were proposed by the trade unions. The chairman of the DMV Alexander Schlicke was appointed to the war office. This was the first time that a free trade unionist held an official position. The state recognition of the trade unions as professional representatives of workers' interests was achieved. Various committees were made up of equal numbers of employee and employer representatives. In factories important to the war effort, union participation was introduced in some areas .

Since then, the unions have also been able to gain a foothold in large companies. The companies saw the law as an exceptional law against employers, while the trade unions celebrated it as a great success in their war policy and a move towards an organized economy . However, the law also meant an even closer identification with the measures of the state and thus a loss of autonomy. As a result, officials and members sometimes drifted further apart. On the face of it, however, the law resulted in a revival of the trade unions. The number of members rose sharply again after 1916 without reaching the pre-war level.

Way to revolution

November Revolution 1918: Revolutionary soldiers with the Red Flag on November 9th in front of the Brandenburg Gate in Berlin

The increasing hardship on the home front led to increasing dissatisfaction among the workers. Local strikes have become more frequent since 1917. First, 40,000 workers at Krupp in Essen went on strike before the strike spread to the Rhenish-Westphalian industrial area, Berlin and other cities and regions. In January 1918 this affected the armaments industry throughout the entire Reich. The number of strikers in the January strikes exceeded the million mark. In the strikes, political dissatisfaction was combined with social hardship.

The leading minds and organizers came in particular from the core workforce. They had often gained experience in the labor movement as SPD members and trade unionists before the war. The most famous group were the Revolutionary Obleute in Berlin and other cities. These were close to the USPD and council democratic ideas . They developed grassroots and business-oriented forms of industrial action that differed from those of the centralized unions. The chairmen had an influence above all in big cities. However, one should not overestimate the scope of this opposition, as the number of union members increased sharply during this period and was hardly affected by the unrest in other sectors.

Nevertheless, the mass strikes in the arms industry were part of a gradually growing revolutionary mood. Against this background, the trade unions pushed for reforms. They were ready to change their systems, but didn't step too much themselves to help. Gustav Bauer , the second chairman of the free trade unions, joined Max von Baden's cabinet at the beginning of October as head of the new Reich Labor Office . The October reforms appeared to the leaders of the free and Christian trade unionists as a great success and a decisive step towards democracy. They wanted to keep going and prevent a revolution from breaking out. This did not succeed, and neither the MSPD nor the free trade unions initially had any significant influence on the November Revolution . This changed with the formation of the Council of People's Representatives . The free trade unions supported his policy. However, they did not play a significant part in the formation of the new government.

Weimar Republic

November Agreement

Hugo Stinnes was significantly involved in the Stinnes-Legien Agreement on the employer's side

Concerns about a revolutionary collapse caused the trade unions and employers to approach one another during the war. The first negotiations for a cooperation failed in early 1918 due to resistance from heavy industry. This only changed in the last weeks of the war. On the business side, concessions to the trade unions were the lesser evil to prevent a possible nationalization of big industry. On November 15, employers and trade unions agreed on the so-called Stinnes Legien or November Agreement . In it, the employers now also recognized the trade unions as the appointed representatives of the employees' interests and guaranteed full freedom of association. Furthermore, the collective agreement system and the establishment of workers' committees in companies with more than 50 employees were approved. Support was withdrawn from the yellow business unions and the eight-hour day with full pay was introduced. Employers and trade unions have created work records with equal representation and arbitration committees have been introduced. The unions had thus pushed through demands for which they had fought for decades. On the basis of the November Agreement, the Central Working Group of Industrial and Commercial Employers and Employees (ZAG) was founded on December 4, 1918 . For the unions, these results were a step towards democratizing the economy. However, the courtesy of employers only proved to be limited to the immediate revolutionary period. In the unions themselves, especially in the DMV, the agreements were heavily criticized. The Nuremberg Congress of Free Trade Unions in mid-1919, however, approved them by a majority. The DMV left the ZAG in October 1919, and unions followed in the following years.

Political policy decisions

First Reich Congress of Workers 'and Soldiers' Councils in the Prussian House of Representatives in Berlin. On the ministerial bench from right to left the people's representatives Barth, Ebert, Landsberg, Scheidemann

On a local basis, trade unionists had, in some cases, played a leading role in the workers and soldiers' councils . A considerable number of the majority Social Democratic delegates at the Reichsrätekongress from December 16 to 21, 1918 were full-time trade unionists. They rejected a council-democratic structure of the state. The unions tried to isolate the radical currents in the council movement. The members of the workers 'and soldiers' councils from their ranks tried to integrate the union leadership into a concept that the councils only wanted to exist until the National Assembly and that they should not have any co-determination rights in the economy.

Gustav Bauer was second chairman of the general commission of the trade unions, Minister in Scheidemann's cabinet and Reich Chancellor

The election to the German National Assembly did not result in a socialist majority, as had been hoped by the free trade unions. Nonetheless, the trade unions were staunch supporters of the republic . A third of the MSPD MPs in the National Assembly were some high-ranking officials of the free trade unions. With Gustav Bauer, Robert Schmidt and Rudolf Wissell , three leading trade unionists were members of the Scheidemann cabinet . For some time Bauer succeeded Scheidemann as head of government. There were also prominent trade unionists in the following cabinets. It was similar in the countries. The chairman of the woodworkers' association Theodor Leipart became the Württemberg labor minister.

Non-parliamentary concepts such as council democracy continued to be rejected by a majority of the unions. Nonetheless, there were supporters within the trade unionists as well. At the first post-war congress of the free trade unions in Nuremberg in the summer of 1919, Richard Müller presented a detailed political council concept, which was rejected by the majority. At the top of the union there were conflicts between a wing of the traditionalists over Legien and reformers over Leipart. In this dispute, with the support of the SPD, the reformers prevailed, who advocated the creation of works councils . With this, the free trade unions gave up their complete rejection of the councils and in part moved away from the previous location-based organization of the labor movement in favor of the company level.

In economic terms, many workers have called for the socialization of various industries as a step towards socialism. The leadership of the trade unions were skeptical of this. In parts of their own supporters this was seen differently. In the Ruhr area, for example, there was a broad socialization movement . The unions maintained their negative stance on this matter, also because it could not be brought into line with the course set in the November agreement.

Instead, Rudolf Wissell promoted the concept of the common economy . The economy should be operated according to plan and socially controlled. The means of production should remain in private ownership. It should not serve the profit interests of individuals, but the common good . Neither public economy nor socialization could be enforced, also because the respective supporters blocked each other.

In the early days of the Weimar Republic, important decisions were made that corresponded to union demands and goals. Collective agreements were declared legally and generally binding, regulations for hiring and firing employees were made and the eight-hour day was introduced. Central points were even written into the constitution . The Works Council Act of 1920 was also important. However, this was not without controversy in the trade unions, since it did not go far enough, especially for the proponents of a political council system.

Inner development

Membership development

Development of the central associations of the German labor unions 1918–1931
EdED with 250,000 members in the ADGB

The number of union members continued to grow after the revolution. In the first quarter of 1919 the number of members in the free trade unions skyrocketed by 1.81 million to 4.67 million. Overall, the number of members also subsequently increased before a setback set in in connection with inflation .

The number of members rose particularly sharply in sectors that were previously barely organized. These were the state workers, railroad workers, farm workers and similar groups. The same applies to large companies. The unions were also able to advance into new regions. This applied to eastern German agricultural areas or the Saar area, where before the war the employers had severely obstructed the unions. In parts of the Ruhr area and neighboring areas in particular, the Christian trade unions were sometimes stronger than the free organizations.

The structure of the members also changed. The numerical importance of the skilled craftsmen in small and medium-sized enterprises decreased in favor of the less qualified factory workers in large enterprises. The proportion of women also increased significantly. In 1918 it was 25%, but then fell slightly to 20% by 1924. Overall, the ADGB lost almost 50% of its members by 1924, compared to 1920.

The drastic decline in membership during the inflationary period continued even further in 1924, which was marked by austerity measures. In 1925 the numbers stagnated, only to plummet in 1926. The low point was only reached this year. The ADGB still had 3.9 million members at that time.

In the following years until 1930 the number of members increased again. But they never reached the level of the early 1920s. With regard to workers' organizations, the ADGB clearly remained the dominant association. It looked different with the employee organizations. The stagnating free trade union AfA-Bund was overtaken by the Christian-national associations. The General German Civil Service Association also lagged behind the DBB .

As a result of the global economic crisis , the number of members, especially in the workers' unions, has again fallen sharply since 1930. The decline was less pronounced for white-collar unions. The trend towards the more nationally oriented associations to the detriment of the AfA Federal continued. Overall, the ADGB associations lost more than a quarter of their members between 1929 and 1932. In some associations, such as those of machinists or clothing workers, the loss was even over 40%. Other associations also lost above average. These included the building trade union, the factory workers, the tobacco workers and the textile workers.

Restructuring

Member associations of the ADGB at the end of 1928
Surname Number of members
Building trade association 435.156
Garment workers 77,884
Miners 196.049
Bookbinder 55,128
Book printer 82,767
roofer 10,843
railwayman 240.913
Factory workers 457.657
Firefighters 7740
Film union 1300
Barber assistants 4057
gardener 10,518
Community and state workers 243,968
Graphic laborers 40,691
Woodworker 306.660
Hotel, restaurant and cafe employees 27,153
Hat worker 18,509
Coppersmiths 7024
Farm workers 151.273
Leather workers 37,855
Lithographers and lithographers 23,719
painter 58,775
Machinists and stokers 48,568
Metalworker 884.027
Musician 23,055
Food and beverage workers 159,636
Saddler, upholsterer ... 30,614
chimney sweeper 2980
Shoemaker 78,834
Swiss 11,456
Stone workers 68.033
Tobacco workers 75.501
Textile workers 306.137
Transport Association 368.052
Carpenter 107.354

At the first post-war congress of the free trade unions in Nuremberg in 1919, 52 associations were represented, representing 4.8 million members. Although the debate was controversial, the Assembly had retrospectively approved the course of the General Commission on War and Revolution. In addition, other current issues were discussed, some of which have already been addressed. At the congress there was also a reorientation in terms of content and organization. The unions declared themselves to be politically neutral. This was also necessary because there was no longer any unified political workers' movement. This, too, has contributed to the fact that there was no split within the trade unions despite all the internal differences between the supporters of the SPD, USPD and KPD .

The ADGB was founded as a new umbrella organization at the first post-war congress of the free trade unions. The previous general commission was replaced by a board of fifteen members. Carl Legien became chairman. After his death in 1921 Theodor Leipart became chairman. The highest body of the ADGB was the federal congress, which meets every three years. At the local level there were local committees of the ADGB, they replaced the previous local cartels . They brought together the local paying offices of the free trade unions. There have been district committees on this since 1922. The individual trade unions were structured similarly.

At the beginning of the 1930s there were around 6,000 full-time functionaries, the vast majority of whom worked in the local administrations of the individual trade unions. The apparatus at the ADGB board consisted of only about 40 people.

At the trade union congress in Essen in 1922, the industrial association principle was given as a goal. The trend also slowly went in this direction and the number of individual associations fell slightly. The General Free Employees' Association (AfA), founded in 1920, and the General German Civil Service Association, founded in 1922, concluded cooperation agreements with the ADGB in 1923.

By changing the association legislation, the unions organized more youth and women. Organizational work has been strengthened for both groups. Gertrud Hanna was a key figure in the field of women's work .

In addition, general educational work was strengthened. The free trade union seminar was founded there in connection with the University of Cologne . In Frankfurt originated Academy of Labor , in Berlin the technical colleges of business administration were founded, where the trade unions were involved. In 1930 a federal school of the ADGB was founded in Bernau . The theoretical organ Die Arbeit was published in 1924 .

Union opposition

Alwin Brandes was a supporter of the union opposition

A characteristic of the situation in the post-war period was that there was quite a strong opposition within the union that rejected the course of the board. This was particularly well represented in the DMV. 64 of 118 delegates of the DMV at the first post-war congress of the ADGB are to be assigned to the opposition. There was no split, but the opposition was gaining ground in the free trade unions. In the DMV, the opposition had a majority at the 1919 general assembly and, with Alwin Brandes and Robert Dißmann, two members of the board of directors, while Georg Reichel represented the previous majority. The opposition also had a majority in the associations of textile workers and shoemakers. She was an important factor in a number of other associations. Among other things, the different generational experiences of the long-serving functionaries and the numerous new members contributed to this.

Many internal conflicts also reflected the division of the labor movement into MSPD and USPD or KPD. This party changed its union course several times. Initially, it relied on the formation of cells in the free trade unions. In autumn 1919 the party issued the slogan: “Get out of the trade unions!” Some of those who were dissatisfied with the majority course found themselves outside the free trade unions in their own, often syndicalist, associations. These were, for example, the General Workers' Union , the Free Workers' Union of Germany , the Communist-influenced Free Workers' Union (towards Gelsenkirchen) and, since 1921, the Union of manual and mental workers . This association dissolved in 1925 at the urging of the KPD, and the members rejoined the free trade unions. At times, these rival associations had a considerable following, especially in large companies in the Ruhr area and in central Germany. After 1923/24, however, they lost their importance. In 1929 the Communist Revolutionary Trade Union Opposition arose .

Development until the end of inflation

Kapp putsch

Demonstration against the Kapp Putsch

The trade unions played a decisive role in ending the Kapp Putsch . The right-wing putsch put the republic in grave danger, especially since the Reichswehr refused to take action against the rebels. On March 13, 1920, ADGB and AfA-Bund called for a general strike. This was supported in the following days by the KPD, the Christian trade unions and the German Association of Officials. After all, 12 million workers were on strike. Not least the general strike contributed to the fact that the putschists had to give up on March 17th.

The trade unions initially continued the strike and raised demands for the dismissal of incriminated people like Gustav Noske or Wolfgang Heine and for the democratization of the administration. Overall, they hoped for a general reorganization of politics and, on the economic level, the socialization of the economy. When the new cabinets were formed in the Reich and Prussia, representatives of the trade unions in particular were to be taken into account, and one dreamed of a pure workers' government. The government made certain non-binding commitments. After Noske's resignation, the general strike ended on March 22nd. The negotiations to form a workers' government failed not only because of resistance from the center and the DDP . The USPD refused to sit in a cabinet with “worker murderers” and Legien was reluctant to take on the post of Chancellor. Finally, a cabinet was formed under Hermann Müller . The various commitments to the unions, including socialization, were not implemented.

In the Ruhr area, riots and the formation of a Red Ruhr Army had already begun during the general strike. Carl Severing in particular reached an agreement with the rebels in the Bielefeld Agreement . But when the Müller government refused to recognize this and threatened violence, the strike was resumed. Against the will of ADGB, depreciation covenant SPD and USPD the Army marched into the Ruhr area and struck the Ruhr uprising bloodily. The political influence of the trade unions continued to decline when a bourgeois government under Constantin Fehrenbach was formed after the Reichstag elections of 1920 .

Ruhr occupation

Civilian and Occupier, 1923

The crisis year 1923 began with the occupation of the Ruhr by French and Belgian troops. The area was intended as a productive pledge for the German reparation obligations . The free trade unions immediately condemned the move as an act of violence. They joined the call of the government under Wilhelm Cuno for passive resistance. Funding the Resistance greatly fueled inflation.

Against this background, too, the trade unions were increasingly skeptical of the resistance. The positions of the government, which wanted to hold on to the resistance, and the free trade unions, which were pushing for an agreement with the occupiers, diverged. The unions urged the government to open negotiations on April 21, but to no avail. In the end, the government submitted proposals for resolving the reparations problem, but the French rejected them. On May 9th, the unions backed the government demonstratively. Although it became increasingly clear that the resistance was making less and less sense, out of consideration for the government, the unions avoided proclaiming an end. During this period, union pronouncements were not always devoid of nationalistic undertones.

Union work and inflation

Inflation Consensus and Wage Policy
July 1923 in front of the Berlin Reichsbank, money transport with bags

In the early 1920s, trade union work in the narrower sense was increasingly characterized by increasing monetary devaluation. Initially, this had advantages for both companies and employees. Inflation made the German economy more competitive internationally, revitalized the economy and had positive effects on the labor market. In contrast to other countries, Germany was spared a post-war depression.

This was one aspect that led to an informal inflationary consensus among employers and unions, neither of which had any real interest in currency stabilization. Nevertheless, wages had to be adjusted to the ever increasing price increases. The consumers had to bear the costs, which in turn led to new wage demands. However, it became more and more difficult to compensate for the rising cost of living in wage negotiations. Wage negotiations became necessary at ever shorter intervals. In 1922 these took place weekly. After all, in 1923 wages could only be adjusted to rising inflation by means of a cost of living index. The real wages declined from the prior 1900-1923 to 60%. The unions did not have a viable stabilization strategy. In particular, they demanded the taxation of material assets, profit skimming, the strengthening of mass purchasing power and an active job creation policy after unemployment had risen sharply. However, the proposals were not well thought out and not very suitable to solve the basic problem of inflation. The labor disputes of the early 1920s often ended in defeat and the results were in any case outdated after a short time.

Fight for the eight-hour day

In addition to wage policy, the question of working hours played a central role. In the Ruhr area there had been massive efforts, including strikes, since the end of 1918 to achieve a six-hour shift. In 1919/20 this was combined with demands for socialization. Ultimately, these attempts failed. With a view to the reparations demands in 1920, the trade unions also agreed to a shift agreement in the coal and steel industry that allowed working hours to be extended. This was seen as a success by employers. Dissatisfaction with the trade unions' concessions increased the number of syndicalist organizations. In southern Germany, too, efforts were made to achieve shorter working hours than those agreed at the end of 1918. There were lockouts there by employers in 1922. The conflict ended in the defeat of the unions.

The eight-hour day agreed in 1918 was increasingly questioned by employers. The question had to be resolved politically because the previous regulation was based only on a demobilization ordinance. The dispute over working hours contributed significantly to the resignation of Gustav Stresemann's cabinet on October 3, 1923. After the SPD left the government on November 3rd, a working time ordinance made it possible to extend working hours. The government reacted to pressure from the Ruhr industry. The trade unions, which until then had been able to prevent all attempts to extend working hours, did not see themselves strong enough to offer vigorous resistance against the background of high unemployment and the wave of withdrawals in the organizations. At the end of 1923, the unions had reached their lowest point of post-war development in terms of membership development and their influence. On January 16, 1924, the ADGB resigned from the meanwhile meaningless central working group with employers.

Weakening of the unions

After the formation of bourgeois governments, the trade unions also lacked partners in politics. In many areas of social and economic policy, the trade unions were unable to penetrate with their ideas. In 1923, the regulation of the arbitration system restricted collective bargaining autonomy. If the employer and employee did not reach an agreement, the Reich Labor Ministry could, if necessary, declare a previously issued arbitration award to be binding against both parties. The unions criticized this, but especially in their weak phase between 1924 and 1926, they had to make use of the arbitration bodies because otherwise they would have had no chance at all against the employers' side. Even when the situation of the trade unions had improved again, they did not seek any fundamental changes.

Not least because of disappointment with the poor social situation and the unsuccessful representation of interests, there were massive withdrawals from the unions. The financial situation of the organizations was severely burdened by the devaluation of the invested financial assets and the falling membership fees. Services had to be canceled, officials were dismissed and newspapers were discontinued.

Relative stabilization phase

Organizational recovery and union business

Headquarters of the German Metalworkers' Association on Alte Jakobstrasse in Berlin-Kreuzberg (October 1930)

After the slump at the end of the inflationary period, it was not only the membership of the trade unions that gradually increased again. The organizational structures also recovered. A number of district secretariats, which were closed due to the crisis, were filled again. Overall, the administration was expanded. The number of member associations continued to decline. But there was no clear implementation of the industrial association system.

The phase between inflation and the global economic crisis was the heyday of the cultural, social and educational activities of the trade unions. Numerous training facilities, legal information centers (workers' secretariats) and libraries have been set up. The smaller, financially weak associations in particular urged the development of central institutions of the ADGB.

Press work was also intensified and the publications made more public. But new papers were also founded. With the journal Die Arbeit, a theoretical organ was created. Together with the SPD, the Research Center for Economic Policy was founded in 1925 under the direction of Fritz Naphtali . With the gradual decline of the intra-union opposition, general relations with the SPD were also strengthened. However, the implementation of a plan for corporate membership of the free trade unions in the SPD did not materialize.

In the second half of the 1920s the public service enterprises flourished. This was partly done by the trade unions. They participated in others. Economic activities took place within the framework of the capitalist system. The bank of workers, employees and civil servants was founded in 1923/24. It experienced an enormous boom in the following years. Public-sector construction companies joined forces to form the Association of Social Construction Companies . Deutsche Wohnungsfürsorge AG , Volksfürsorge , various consumer cooperatives and publishers were also successful .

Economic situation and wage policy

Basically, the economic situation improved after overcoming inflation. Industrial production increased. The adjustment to international competition increased the urge to rationalize and mechanize production. This increased labor productivity significantly. But this also meant an intensification of the work, for example through Taylorism . In spite of the relatively good economic situation, there was now considerable unemployment. Instead of the “ golden twenties ”, economic history speaks of a phase of relative stability. This was interrupted several times by economic slumps, such as in 1924 and 1925/26. The upswing also benefited workers. Between 1928 and 1930, real wages exceeded the level of 1913. The extent to which this exceeded the efficiency of the economy is a matter of dispute in economics (Borchardt controversy). The question was already controversial among contemporaries. The unions argued that the higher wages and increased purchasing power would have boosted the economy. Employers claimed that wage levels would affect competitiveness. In particular, they criticized the compulsory state arbitration and called for changes in this area. The unions had an unclear position on this issue. On the one hand, they did not want to be deprived of their right to strike, and on the other hand, given the employers' anti-tariff stance, they could not do without arbitration.

In the first few years after inflation, employers were the clearly stronger side. The year 1924 was a high point in German industrial action history. In total, over 36 million working days were lost to strikes and lockouts. The largest part, three fifths, was due to lockouts by employers. In the following years, too, the employers mostly proved to be stronger and the unions were on the defensive, especially until 1928. Nevertheless, with the help of state arbitration bodies, wages were able to improve from their low in 1923 in the following year. In the following period, however, real wages hardly rose due to the rise in prices. This was not the case until 1927/28.

Working time issue

In 1924, the issue of working hours was initially the focus of disputes between employers and unions. Numerous labor disputes were waged against the extension of working hours. In May 1924 there was a labor dispute in the Ruhr mining industry. It wasn't just about working hours, but also about the threat of massive wage losses. In this conflict, state arbitration tended towards the employer side, especially at the beginning. In the end, 380,000 miners were locked out. Employers expanded the industrial action to include heavy industry. The free miners' union is ultimately inferior in this conflict.

Overall, employers took advantage of the government's working time ordinance to extend working hours. In the metal and textile industry, the 50-hour week was overlapped, and sometimes 60 hours were worked. In other sectors such as construction or the wood industry, it remained at 48 hours. At first, the unions were significantly more successful in regulating vacation, even if this only meant a few days off.

In the years that followed, the unions increasingly urged a return to the eight-hour day. In 1926 the ADGB called for a working time emergency law. He referred on the one hand to the high unemployment figures and on the other hand to the long overtime of employees. The SPD also campaigned for change. A working time law was passed in 1927. Despite improvements, this continued to allow numerous exceptions to the eight-hour day, so that the unions rejected the law. In the medium term, however, they recognized that the law had brought about the fundamental recognition of the eight-hour day.

In fact, the number of employees with a 48-hour week had increased significantly to over 70%. Overall, the unions had moved closer to their goal. In the face of rationalization and unemployment, they even advocated limiting working hours to less than 48 hours per week.

Social policy successes and goals

In 1927, a major socio-political advance was achieved with unemployment insurance . The unions and their affiliated parties worked together to get the law through. The ADGB celebrated the law as an important step towards economic democracy . This meant a participation of the workers in the economic decision-making processes. Fritz Naphtali formulated in 1928, “that capitalism can also be bent before it is broken.” On the one hand, it was about strengthening internal co-determination by the works councils. Outside of the factories, the unions had to endeavor to democratize the economy at the supra-company level. The concept of economic democracy should help to link the daily reform practice with the socialist ultimate goal. Ultimately, it was a matter of involving the trade unions in an equal management of the economy. When the Social Democrats returned to government in 1928, business circles feared that they might make efforts to implement the concept of economic democracy.

Rubble dispute and the consequences

The trade unionist Rudolf Wissell (left around 1930) was Reich Labor Minister in the grand coalition

The climax of the conflicts between employers and employees in the phase of relative stabilization was the Ruhreisenstreit of 1928. It was about demands of the unions in the Rhenish-Westphalian iron industry. In the course of this there was a mass lockout by employers. The Reich Association of German Industry and the Association of German Employers' Associations supported the position of employers in the Ruhr area. Carl Severing was quite accommodating to the employers in his arbitrator. Nevertheless, they criticized the decision massively. The tough attitude of the employers and their criticism of the state arbitration system was also an expression of the conflict between a social interventionist state and an economy gradually distancing itself from the Weimar democracy.

The political expectations of the unions towards the Müller government were high and were only partially fulfilled. The ratification of the Washington Working Time Agreement was blocked. Because of general political setbacks, criticism of the government grew in the SPD and trade unions. The central point of contention was how to deal with the financially overburdened unemployment insurance. Employers and the ruling party DVP wanted to cut benefits. For the unions, the defense of insurance had a similar symbolic value as the eight-hour day a few years ago. The unions advocated an increase in contribution rates to avoid a reduction in benefits. The DVP decidedly refused. The majority of the ministers from the SPD agreed to a compromise proposed by Heinrich Brüning with a view to a possible breach of the coalition , which in the foreseeable future, however, resulted in cuts in benefits.

Reich Labor Minister Wissell and the representatives from the ranks of the trade unions brought the majority of the SPD parliamentary group behind them, saying that if the party should decide against the ideas of the unions, the close ties between the party and the unions could break. The group then voted against the compromise proposal. This termination of allegiance by the party and ADGB led to the end of the Müller government. Both of them had reached the limit of the reasonableness of concessions if one did not want to lose one's own profile.

Great Depression

Crisis development and weakening of the organization

Mass misery at the height of the crisis: the dining room of a homeless asylum in Berlin-Prenzlauer Berg in 1932

In retrospect, the peak of the economic recovery phase had already passed in 1928. Since 1930 in particular, production and employment have declined noticeably. This also went hand in hand with falling government revenues and, at the same time, increased spending caused by unemployment. The Brüning government rejected debt-financed crisis spending and focused on balancing the budget. The unions and employers supported price-cutting measures to stimulate exports. Linked to this, however, was a reduction in wages and social benefits. As a result, workers' incomes fell sharply, while cartel-determined prices for industrial products hardly fell. Overall, the deflationary price-cutting policy made the crisis worse. One of their main indicators was unemployment. In 1928 it was already 1.89 million on average, rose to over 3 million in 1930, to 4.5 million in 1931 and reached at least 6.1 million in 1932.

The loss of membership, unemployment and wage losses severely weakened the efficiency of the trade unions during the crisis. The income of the free trade unions fell significantly, while the number of those in need of assistance increased. As a result, benefits had to be reduced. Therefore, the organizations tried to reduce administrative and personnel costs. On the other hand, spending on strikes fell significantly. The union companies also suffered from the crisis.

Strikes were hardly feasible due to high unemployment and the weakened organization. Their number fell by a third from 1929 to 1931. If there were labor disputes on the part of the unions, these were mostly defensive strikes to prevent deterioration. The employers were now clearly at the fore and they could also hope for favorable arbitrators. As a result, wages fell significantly.

Demand for shorter working hours

At the beginning of the crisis, the unions could not foresee the extent of the problems ahead. It appeared to be an economic slowdown, as had happened several times in recent years. It was not until the spring of 1930 that unemployment had not fallen significantly that the unions began to suspect that it was more than a brief economic slump. They pressed for the safeguarding and fairer distribution of the remaining work. This should be done in particular by introducing the 40-hour week. The proponents were aware that only a comparatively small number of new job opportunities could be created in this way. Nevertheless, the demand for a reduction in working hours remained at the center of the union's argument. In addition, the demands for a price reduction to stimulate domestic demand played a role. However, this did not allow it to gain acceptance with the governments, who continued to focus on improving export opportunities. In doing so, they followed the urging of the industry and began a policy of social cuts through emergency ordinances , which further weakened the internal market.

Government of Brüning and organizational competition

The free trade unions joined the Iron Front

After Brüning took office, the entrepreneurs, supported by a changed state arbitration policy, pushed through massive wage cuts. A labor dispute broke out in the Mansfeld copper mine. The employers were not able to implement the planned wage cut of 15%, but wages fell by at least 9.5%. In the Berlin metal industry there was a strike because of wage cuts, but the unions broke it off. The fact that the free trade unions shared the SPD's policy of tolerating the Brüning government played a role in this less than energetic stance. After the dissolution of the Reichstag in 1930, the free trade unions supported the SPD in the election campaign. The unions wanted to make the election a referendum on the government's abuse of Article 48 of the Imperial Constitution. In the election call, the free trade unions also turned against communists and National Socialists. The DVP and DNVP were seen as a real threat to democratic socialism.

The mention of the KPD and the NSDAP was not accidental, as the free trade unions grew up in direct competition from both sides. In the autumn of 1930 the KPD founded the Union of Metal Workers in Berlin and the Union of Miners. These were part of the Revolutionary Trade Union Opposition . The founding of the RGO went back to resolutions of the Comintern . Their importance was initially rather modest. The RGO organized 260,000 to 310,000 members in the spring of 1932. It is noteworthy that 75% of them were non-party.

With the National Socialist company cell organization, the NSDAP also had a union-like structure. Both NSBO ​​and RGO were particularly successful among young people, unskilled workers and the unemployed. The RGO had its regional focus in the Ruhr area, Central Germany and Upper Silesia . In addition to mining, it also played a certain role in the chemical industry.

Overall, however, the free trade unions remained the clearly dominant force among the directional trade unions. In the works council elections in 1931, the Hirsch-Duncker trade unions got 1,560 seats, the RGO 4664, the Christian unions 10,956 and the free unions 115,671 seats. However, the importance of the RGO was significantly higher in individual sectors. In mining, the free trade unions had 45.1% of the votes in 1931, while the RGO had 24.7%. In the Ruhr area, the ADGB only came to 36.4% and the RGO to 29.9%. Although the numerical importance of the RGO remained limited, the free trade unions felt compelled to invest a lot of energy in the defense. The strict demarcation from the KPD and RGO remained in place until the end of the republic. The same applies to the confrontation of the communists against the free trade unions and the SPD, defamed as "trade union bigwigs" and " social fascists ". A united front could not come about in this way.

The 1930 Reichstag election resulted in massive votes for the NSDAP . The ADGB, like the SPD, subsequently relied on toleration of the Briining government in order to prevent the silent dictatorship from turning into an open dictatorship. After the end of the Brüning cabinet, there was fear of a coalition of Alfred Hugenberg and Adolf Hitler . The fight against the NSDAP and for the preservation of parliamentary democracy became a concern of the free trade unions after the September elections.

Fritz Tarnow expressed the fear that if the National Socialists came to power, the existence of the trade unions could be in danger. Only an early economic upswing would reduce social tensions and thus stop the influx of radicals. Talks with employers about a common concept to stimulate the economy failed, although they had converged on many points.

The Brüning government was not very accommodating to the ADGB, as the various emergency ordinances showed, but the ADGB stuck to the tolerance. The possible interventions in collective bargaining law, but also political developments such as the founding of the short-lived Harzburg Front, led to closer ties between the unions. This was of no use. Various emergency ordinances subsequently interfered with collective bargaining law. Without any real leverage, the unions could only protest without result.

Also out of concern about a possible takeover of power by the NSDAP, the trade unions organized the so-called hammer clubs in the factories and joined the Iron Front . Like the SPD, the free trade unions also supported the re-election of Hindenburg in the spring of 1932 as the lesser evil in comparison with Hitler.

WTB plan

Fritz Baade was one of the authors of the WTB plan

Vladimir Woytinsky , head of the statistical office of the ADGB, presented a plan to stimulate the general economy, which was discussed by the ADGB in March 1931 as an action program to stimulate the economy. In contrast to the previous line, the program called for a price increase, as this would lead to a reduction in loans and thus to a revival of the economy. Woytinsky’s demand for an active economic policy was controversially discussed in the trade unions and the SPD. Fritz Naphtali in particular stood out as a critic, who feared the plan would have an inflationary effect. Fritz Tarnow criticized the fact that the plan ultimately wanted to save the private economic order instead of overcoming it.

Together with Franz Tarnow and Fritz Baade, Woytinski's plan was further developed into a job creation program. It became known as the WTB-Plan after the main authors. The final version was published in January 1932. A program of public works totaling 2 billion Reichsmarks was intended to help one million unemployed people find employment again for one year.

In April 1932 the ADGB organized a crisis congress that specified the possible measures. The state and state-affiliated companies such as the Reichsbahn and Reichspost were to commission infrastructure measures that would enable the unemployed to find employment. Among other things, this should be financed through a job creation bond. The crisis congress also called for greater control and influence of the state on the economy.

The guidelines for restructuring the economy published by the ADGB and the AfA-Bund in June 1932 essentially provided for the nationalization of key industries, banks, and energy and transport companies. The rest of the economy should be organized according to a planned economy. The programs were criticized not only by employers, but also by social democrats and from within their own ranks. Overall, however, it is noteworthy that the ADGB passed a program that was based at least in part on an anti-cyclical economic policy .

Final phase of the republic

During the BVG strike in 1932, RGO and NSBO ​​went on strike together against the will of the ADGB

With the WTB plan, the free trade unions had a counter-concept to Brüning's policy. As a result, they also acted more critically without giving up their policy of tolerance. They expected the government under Franz von Papen to intensify the pro-business and anti-worker course. Because of their weakness, they could not do much more than protest against the emergency ordinances. In some areas, such as the question of job creation and the establishment of the voluntary labor service , the trade unions have worked with the government without understanding this as tolerance.

Like the SPD, the free trade unions did not dare to oppose the Prussian strike. In contrast to the Kapp Putsch, for example, in view of the millions of unemployed people saw no chance in a general strike.

In 1932, the NSDAP came more and more into focus as the greatest threat to the republic. A united front with the RGO or KPD did not come about due to the fundamentally different goals and mutual mistrust. After the emergency ordinance was issued in September 1932, a wave of strikes broke out with the aim of preventing impending wage losses. However, the unions were reluctant to support them. This also applies to the BVG strike in Berlin . Against the will of the responsible union, the RGO and NSBO ​​jointly called for a work stoppage.

The free trade unions hoped for a better relationship from Kurt von Schleicher's government than they did with the Papen cabinet. In fact, Schleicher soon sought contact with the unions. He overturned some parts of the September Emergency Ordinance and made job creation measures the top priority. Schleicher tried to get union-oriented members of the Reichstag in all directions balanced and to create a parliamentary majority by forming a "union axis". The moderate wing of the NSDAP around Gregor Strasser should also be involved . The goal failed because Strasser was overthrown and the Christian unions reacted negatively. The free trade unions remained waiting under pressure from the SPD. But they were basically ready to work together. After the end of the Schleicher government, the unions appealed to Reich President von Hindenburg not to form a cabinet that was socially reactionary.

The End

The free trade union - official bulletin of the ADGB in Hamburg from April 19, 1933: Call for May 1, 1933
Adolf Hitler on "German Labor Day" on May 1, 1933

On January 30, 1933, Adolf Hitler was appointed Reich Chancellor. A statement by the ADGB said that the vital interests of the entire workforce were at stake.

“In order to effectively ward off attacks against the constitution and popular rights in an emergency, cold blood and prudence are the first imperatives. Do not allow yourself to be led into hasty and therefore harmful individual actions. "

There was no call for mass actions. While the KPD spoke of a general strike, the ADGB refused. Leipart gave the slogan "Organization - not demonstration is the order of the day." In retrospect, this meant surrender without a fight. However, there was no real chance to resist by force if necessary.

Apparently they did not seriously expect the trade unions to be broken up and began to adjust to the new conditions. The role of the trade unions as a “school of responsibility” was emphasized, and Leipart emphasized the “services of the trade unions for the people and the state.” Instead of internationalism, they wanted to contribute to the reconciliation of “nation, trade unions and socialism”. The free trade unions also began to distance themselves from the SPD. Articles by ADGB functionaries such as Lothar Erdmann and Walter Pahl promoted this reorientation.

Even after the March elections in 1933, the real threat was not recognized. When the Nazis violently cracked down on trade unionists and their institutions in various locations, these appeared to be local events. The adjustment came to the brink of self-disclosure. The ADGB executive committee recognized the right of the state to intervene in disputes between employers and employees, should the general interest make this necessary. Even the previous form of organization was ready to be sacrificed. “The safeguarding of workers' interests stands above the form of organization.” One had illusions when one said: “The social tasks of the trade unions must be fulfilled, regardless of the nature of the state regime.” On April 9, the ADGB declared the in “ To put the self-governing organizations of the workers created by decades of work in the service of the new state. "

A little later, Leipart and the other chairmen of the trade union umbrella organizations discussed the future form of their organizations. When the NSBO ​​representative demanded that Leipart should vacate his post in favor of a National Socialist, however, this refused. The free trade unions were not without support from the workers, as the works council elections in spring 1933 showed. The free trade unions still received over 70% of the vote, while the NSBO ​​only got 11.7%. Because of this clarity, the government finally canceled the elections.

The result increased the government's will to crush the unions. In addition to the talks with the NSBO, the unions tried in vain to bring about a unified union at the last minute . At the end of April 1933 a group of leaders of the united trade unions was formed. The association emphasized the will to contribute to the reorganization of economic and social life.

When the government announced a reinterpretation of the previous day of struggle for the working class on National Labor Day , the ADGB expressly welcomed this. The federal committee called for festive participation. Shortly afterwards, the ADGB broke off its contacts with the International Trade Union Confederation.

After members of the free trade unions also took part in the celebrations on May 1st, the unions were smashed on May 2nd. Their buildings have been occupied, trade unionists have been captured and murdered. On May 3, the remaining unions submitted to the National Socialist "Action Committee for the Protection of German Labor." This meant the end of the trade union movement in Germany for twelve years.

Resistance and persecution during the Nazi regime

Recent research assumes that the resistance of former trade unionists from the free trade union movement is of far greater importance in terms of scope and intensity than previously assumed. Thus it can be shown that a large number of leading functionaries of the free trade unions, who failed with their adjustment policy in the spring of 1933, some only a few months later rallied to resist the Nazi regime. You had initially underestimated its brutality. As a rule, the resistance efforts - especially among the metal, construction and transport workers - were initially aimed at rebuilding the organizations in the illegality as a secret circle. Contacts with the illegal Reich leadership of the trade unions , the exile executive committee of the SPD (Sopade) and international trade union organizations demonstrate the relevance of illegal trade union organization. With regard to all former free trade union associations, some very extensive acts of resistance can be proven. A number of resistance members from the trade union movement collected reports on the situation of the workers in the factories and the concrete wage development, as they viewed the Nazi system as fundamentally hostile to the workers. These reports were forwarded to international trade union organizations, among others. From there, support came to counter the Nazi propaganda, including through illegal magazines and leaflets. At the same time, there were also a number of activities - including open sabotage and practical support for forced laborers - to weaken and damage the Nazi regime. Various circles in the Reich continued their illegal work until 1945. Some trade unionists were involved in the resistance surrounding the conspirators in the assassination attempt on Hitler on July 20, 1944. Numerous trade unionists were arrested between 1933 and 1945 for their resistance. Quite a few died in concentration camps or were deliberately murdered. The organized resistance formed the basis for the rebuilding of the unions after the end of the Second World War in both parts of Germany.

Phases and partial organization

Source collections

  • Klaus Schönhoven (edit.): The trade unions in World War I and Revolution 1914–1919. Cologne, 1985 (Sources on the history of the German trade union movement in the 20th century; Vol. 1)
  • Michael Ruck (arr.): The trade unions in the early years of the Weimar Republic 1919–1923. Cologne, 1985 (Sources on the history of the German trade union movement in the 20th century; Vol. 2)
  • Horst A. Kukuck, Dieter Schiffmann (arr.): The trade unions from stabilization to the global economic crisis 1924–1930. Cologne, 1986 (Sources on the history of the German trade union movement in the 20th century; Vol. 3, I and II)
  • Peter Jahn (arr.): The trade unions in the final phase of the republic 1930–1933. Cologne, 1988 (Sources on the history of the German trade union movement in the 20th century, Vol. 4)
  • Siegfried Mielke , Matthias Frese (edit.) The unions in the resistance and in the emigration , Frankfurt / Main 1999 (sources on the history of the German trade union movement in the 20th century, vol. 5), ISBN 3-7663-0905-6

literature

  • Ulrich Borsdorf (ed.): History of the German trade unions. From the beginning until 1945. Cologne, 1987. Therein:
    • Klaus Tenfelde : The emergence of the German trade union movement. Pp. 15-166
    • Klaus Schönhoven : The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire, 1890 to 1918. P. 167–278
    • Michael Schneider : Highs, crises and lows. The trade unions in the Weimar Republic 1918 to 1933. pp. 279–446
  • Detlev Brunner: Bureaucracy and politics of the general German trade union federation. 1918/19 to 1933 (series of publications by the Otto Brenner Foundation 55), Cologne 1992
  • Frank Deppe , Georg Fülberth , Jürgen Harrer (eds.), History of the German trade union movement, Cologne 1983
  • Arno Klönne , Hartmut Reese: The German trade union movement. From the beginning to the present. Hamburg, 1984
  • Stefan Heinz , Siegfried Mielke : Functionaries of the unified association of metal workers in Berlin in the Nazi state. Resistance and persecution (= trade unionists under National Socialism. Persecution - Resistance - Emigration, Vol. 2), Metropol Verlag, Berlin 2012, ISBN 978-3-86331-062-2
  • Siegfried Mielke , Stefan Heinz (eds.) With the assistance of Marion Goers: Functionaries of the German Metalworkers' Association in the Nazi state. Resistance and persecution (= trade unionists under National Socialism. Persecution - Resistance - Emigration, Vol. 1), Metropol-Verlag, Berlin 2012, ISBN 978-3-86331-059-2
  • Siegfried Mielke : Trade unionists in the Nazi state: persecution, resistance, emigration , Essen 2008, ISBN 978-3-89861-914-1
  • Siegfried Mielke : Trade unionist in the Oranienburg and Sachsenhausen concentration camps. Biographisches Handbuch , Vol. 1–4, Berlin 2002–2013, ISBN 3-89468-268-X (Vol. 1), ISBN 3-89468-275-2 (Vol. 2), ISBN 3-89468-280-9 (Vol. 3), ISBN 978-3-86331-148-3 (Vol. 4) [Vol. 2 and 3 ed. in connection with Günter Morsch, Vol. 4 ed. with Stefan Heinz in collaboration with Julia Pietsch]
  • Siegfried Mielke , Günter Morsch (ed.): "Be vigilant that night never falls over Germany again." Trade unionists in concentration camps 1933–1945 . Berlin 2011, ISBN 978-3-86331-031-8
  • Werner Müller: wage war, mass strike, Soviet power. Aims and limits of the Revolutionary Trade Union Opposition (RGO) in Germany 1928 to 1933. Bund-Verlag, Cologne 1988, ISBN 3-7663-3063-2
  • Ludwig Heyde (Ed.): International concise dictionary of the trade union system. 2nd volumes. Berlin 1931/32, fes.de
  • Heinrich Potthoff: Free Trade Unions 1918–1933. The General Union of Trade Unions in the Weimar Republic. Düsseldorf 1987
  • Gerhard A. Ritter (Hrsg.): The rise of the German labor movement. Social democracy and free trade unions in the party system and social milieu of the empire (= writings of the historical college . Colloquia. Vol. 18). With the assistance of Elisabeth Müller-Luckner. Oldenbourg, Munich 1990, ISBN 3-486-55641-X ( digitized version ).
  • Michael Schneider: Under the swastika. Workers and labor movement 1933 to 1939 . Bonn 1999
  • Michael Schneider: A short history of the trade unions. Your development in Germany from the beginning until today . Bonn 1989
  • Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions. Frankfurt am Main 1987
  • Dieter Schuster: Chronology of the German trade union movement from its beginnings to 1918 . With a foreword by Rüdiger Zimmermann and registers by Hubert Woltering. Online version , FES Library, Bonn 2000.
  • Heinrich August Winkler : Workers and the labor movement in the Weimar Republic. 3 volumes. Dietz, Berlin / Bonn 1984 ff.
    • Volume 1: From Revolution to Stabilization. 1918-1924. Berlin / Bonn 1984, ISBN 3-8012-0093-0 .
    • Volume 2: The appearance of normality. 1924-1930. Berlin / Bonn 1985, ISBN 3-8012-0094-9 .
    • Volume 3: The Path to Disaster. 1930-1933. 2nd Edition. Berlin / Bonn 1990, ISBN 3-8012-0095-7 .

Scientific journals

Web links

Individual evidence

  1. cf. naming: Paul Umbreit : Free trade unions . In: International Concise Dictionary of Trade Unions . Berlin, 1931 digitized
  2. cit. after: Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 57.
  3. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 48–59: Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987 pp. 18-24
  4. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 93–97, Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 24-27.
  5. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 100-106.
  6. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 106-110.
  7. ^ Axel Kuhn: The German labor movement . Stuttgart, 2004 p. 88.
  8. ^ Arno Herzig : The General German Workers' Association in German Social Democracy. Depicted in the biography of the functionary Carl Wilhelm Tölcke . Colloquium Verlag, Berlin 1979, pp. 259-263 (supplements to the IWK, vol. 5).
  9. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 88.
  10. ^ Michael Schneider: A short history of the trade unions. Your development in Germany from the beginning until today . Verlag JHW Dietz Nachf., Bonn 1989, p. 40.
  11. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 100-114.
  12. Dieter Fricke: The German labor movement from 1869 to 1914. A manual about their organization and activity in the class struggle . Verlag deb, Berlin 1976, pp. 625-627
  13. Cora Stephan: “Comrades, we mustn't allow ourselves to be carried away by patience!” From the prehistory of social democracy 1862–1878 . Europäische Verlagsanstalt, Frankfurt 1981, p. 178f
  14. ^ Hans Limmer: The German trade union movement . 9th unchanged edition. Günter Olzog Verlag, Munich 1980, p. 26
  15. ^ Michael Schneider: A short history of the trade unions. Your development in Germany from the beginning until today . Verlag JHW Dietz Nachf., Bonn 1989, p. 50.
  16. James J. Sheehan: The German Liberalism. From the beginnings in the 18th century to the First World War. 1770-1914 . Translated by Karl Heinz Siber. CH Beck Verlag, Munich 1983, p. 183.
  17. Heiner Budde: Christian Social on the Ruhr. A popular movement at the heart of industry . KAB, Essen 1988, p. 29.
  18. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 111-121; Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 32, 40 f.
  19. ^ Arno Herzig: The General German Workers' Association in German Social Democracy. Depicted in the biography of the functionary Carl Wilhelm Tölcke . Colloquium Verlag, Berlin 1979, pp. 263-266 (supplements to the IWK, vol. 5).
  20. Dietrich Milles: "... but no one came to the pits to drive on." Labor disputes among Ruhr miners 1867–1878 . Campus Verlag, Frankfurt / New York 1983, pp. 118–127.
  21. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne, 1987 pp. 123-131; Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 30 f., 40; on the strike wave of the 1870s: Lothar Machtan : “With confidence in the just cause.” Strike movements of industrial workers in the 70s of the 19th century . In: Klaus Tenfelde, Heinrich Volksmann (Hrsg.): Strike. On the history of the labor dispute in Germany during industrialization . Munich, 1981 pp. 52-73
  22. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne, 1987 pp. 131-142.
  23. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne, 1987 pp. 142-145
  24. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne, 1987 pp. 145-149
  25. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne, 1987 pp. 149-155
  26. Printed in: Collection of sources for the history of German social policy 1867 to 1914 , Section II: From the Imperial Social Message to the February Decrees of Wilhelm II (1881–1890) , Volume 4: Workers' Law , edited by Wilfried Rudloff, Darmstadt 2008, No. 39.
  27. Wolfgang Jäger / Klaus Tenfelde: Picture history of the German miners' movement . Verlag CH Beck, Munich 1989, pp. 30-35
  28. ^ Klaus Tenfelde: The emergence of the German trade union movement . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne, 1987 pp. 156-165, Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 46-51
  29. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 180f.
  30. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 181-183
  31. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 283-185
  32. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 185
  33. ^ Axel Kuhn: The German labor movement. Stuttgart, 2004 p. 113
  34. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 186-191
  35. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 191-196
  36. cit. after Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire from 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 239.
  37. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 236-242.
  38. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 225-230
  39. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 202-211.
  40. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 228
  41. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 227–235, Axel Kuhn: The German labor movement. Stuttgart, 2004 p. 112
  42. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 212-218
  43. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 219-225
  44. ^ Axel Kuhn: The German labor movement. Stuttgart, 2004 p. 113f.
  45. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 243-247
  46. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 251-254
  47. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 267-272
  48. Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918. In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions. Cologne 1987, pp. 257-262.
  49. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The trade unions as a mass movement in the Wilhelminian Empire 1890 to 1918 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 272-277, Michael Schneider: Heights, crises and depths. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 284-289
  50. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions. Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 121-124. Michael Schneider: Highs, crises and lows. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 289-293
  51. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 293-295, Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, p. 127
  52. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 296f, Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, p. 128
  53. Cf. Heinrich August Winkler : From the revolution to stabilization. Workers and the labor movement in the Weimar Republic 1918 to 1924 . Berlin, Bonn 1984 pp. 159-183.
  54. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 296-300. Heinrich August Winkler: From Revolution to Stabilization. Workers and the labor movement in the Weimar Republic 1918 to 1924 . Berlin / Bonn 1984, pp. 191-205
  55. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 300-304. See the Works Council Act: Heinrich August Winkler: From the Revolution to Stabilization. Workers and the labor movement in the Weimar Republic 1918 to 1924 . Berlin / Bonn 1984, pp. 283-294
  56. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 323–327, Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, p. 137
  57. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 370f., Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 143f.
  58. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 396-397
  59. ^ Paul Umbreit: ADGB In: HDGW p. 23 f.
  60. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 309-315. See: Detlev Brunner: Bureaucracy and Politics of the General German Trade Union Confederation 1918/19 to 1933. Cologne 1992
  61. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 307-309. Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, p. 130 f. Cf. Heinrich August Winkler: From the revolution to stabilization. Workers and the labor movement in the Weimar Republic 1918 to 1924 . Berlin / Bonn 1984, pp. 259-273
  62. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 328-332. Compare: From revolution to stabilization. Workers and the labor movement in the Weimar Republic 1918 to 1924 . Berlin / Bonn 1984, pp. 295-342
  63. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 339-342. Compare: Heinrich August Winkler: From Revolution to Stabilization. Workers and the labor movement in the Weimar Republic 1918 to 1924 . Berlin / Bonn 1984, pp. 553-604. Michael Ruck: The free trade unions in the Ruhr fight 1923 . Cologne, 1986
  64. cf. as a summary of the extensive research, for example: Heike Knortz: Economic history of the Weimar Republic . Göttingen 2010, pp. 35–45
  65. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 333–336, Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 137-139
  66. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 336–346, Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 139–142, vegl .: Michael Schneider: Controversy about working hours. Cologne, 1984 pp. 98-133
  67. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 342-344, Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, p. 142, p. 150-152
  68. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 372 f. Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, p. 147
  69. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 373
  70. summarizing about: Heike Knortz: Economic history of the Weimar Republic . Göttingen 2010, pp. 115–156
  71. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 352–354, Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, p. 153f., P. 157. Cf. Heinrich August Winkler: The appearance of normality. 1924-1930 . Berlin / Bonn 1985, pp. 478-488
  72. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 354-357
  73. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 357-362, Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 254f.
  74. ^ Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions. Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 159-161; see. Heinrich August Winkler: The appearance of normality. 1924-1930. Berlin / Bonn 1985, pp. 606-628.
  75. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 384–387, Ders .: “In full knowledge of the scope of the current conflict.” The Ruhreisenstreit 1928/29. In: Lutz Niethammer u. a. (Ed.): People don't make their story of their own free will, but they make it themselves . Invitation to a history of the people in North Rhine-Westphalia. Essen 2006, pp. 136-139. Heinrich August Winkler: The appearance of normality. 1924-1930 . Berlin / Bonn 1985, pp. 557-572
  76. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 416-418, Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, p. 166
  77. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 390-394. See Heike Knortz: Economic history of the Weimar Republic . Göttingen 2010, pp. 200-272
  78. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 397 f., Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 171f.
  79. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions. Cologne 1987, pp. 398-401. Ders .: Dispute over working hours. Cologne, 1984, pp. 134-146
  80. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 422f.
  81. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 422f., Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 169f.
  82. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 423-429.
  83. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 401-407. Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 173f.
  84. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 429-434. Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 174-176
  85. cit. according to: Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, p. 435
  86. Michael Schneider: ups, downs and crises. The unions in the Weimar Republic from 1918 to 1933 . In: Ulrich Borsdorf (Hrsg.): History of the German trade unions . Cologne 1987, pp. 434–441, Klaus Schönhoven: The German trade unions . Frankfurt am Main 1987, pp. 179-183
  87. ^ Siegfried Mielke , Stefan Heinz (eds.) With the collaboration of Marion Goers: Functionaries of the German Metal Workers' Association in the Nazi State. Resistance and persecution (= trade unionists under National Socialism. Persecution - resistance - emigration. Volume 1). Metropol, Berlin 2012, ISBN 978-3-86331-059-2 , p. 11 ff.
This version was added to the list of articles worth reading on November 16, 2012 .